![]() |
Home
| Databases
| WorldLII
| Search
| Feedback
Alternative Law Journal |
![]() |
The Government encourages businesses to regulate themselves rather than rely on the Government to do it for them. Effective self-regulation has the potential to achieve greater and lasting improvements in business practices by using negotiation and consultation rather than prescriptive legislation and enforcement. Consumers can benefit from a greater focus by business on customer service and on being responsible for its behaviour. [2]
Codes of Conduct, as
self-regulatory tools, have become an integral feature of the consumer
protection landscape.[3] A number of
industries have moved to adopt Codes of Conduct, including: life insurance,
general insurance, smart cards, computerised
check-out systems, electronic funds
transfer and, most recently, direct marketing. This Brief will touch on the
perceived problems
with the principles underlying the development of codes using
the Australian Direct Marketing Association’s (ADMA) recent Code
of
Practice as an example of what we can expect from codes as a form of consumer
protection.
The assumption on which Codes of Conduct are built is worth
serious examination. Prevailing economic theory discourages government
regulation, preferring market participants themselves to set, make rules for,
and run the ‘playing field’:
Since the late 1970s there has been a revival of what is variously called ‘free-market’ or ‘libertarian’ economics and political philosophy, whose basic premise is that state intervention is a bad thing. The proponents of these views appear to make the basic ... assumption that the free market is always the most effective regulator, which in the long run produces the most beneficial effect for consumers and for society as a whole.[4]
Codes are
based on the economic theory that the market is best placed to provide good
outcomes for consumers:
While the obvious mechanism to provide protection for consumers is state intervention, either by providing the means for the less powerful to restrain abuses of market power or by direct regulation, government regulation may sometimes be inefficient and, even though it prevents harm to consumers, may create a greater harm, especially lack of profitability for the providers of goods and services. The result is either that prices rise to the detriment of consumers or that businesses become unprofitable and fail, leaving the market, and either reduce the level of competition between suppliers of the particular commodity or simply make the commodity unavailable. The suggested solution is that the suppliers of the commodity should be left to develop amongst themselves voluntary codes of conduct ... [5]
The market,
however, can and does fail participants and, as has been noted, has historically
failed consumers in particular:
[T]he very existence of consumer protection laws both in legislative form, and as expressed in judgments of the courts which provide the basis for most of the rules of consumer protection, is evidence of the fact that the forces of the market have failed, often with disastrous consequences.[6]
Despite the prevailing economic theory that suggests the
market is always the best regulator, it is, for example, a given that consumers
have a right to product safety enshrined by
legislation.[7] The right to privacy,
however, appears to be a matter for the market place. If the ADMA Code is an
example of the self-regulatory
response to privacy protection, there may be real
fears for the loss of privacy. Strong criticism has been levelled at the ADMA
Code
by virtually all privacy advocates in Australia. The ADMA Code presented
for authorisation allowed, for example, unsolicited phone
calls at practically
all times of the day, each day of the
week.[8]
The benefit of Codes
is that they will drive best practice and increased consumer protection through
mechanisms that are more flexible,
targeted to a specific industry, less costly
and more certain.[9] The great fear is
that these schemes will create a facade of consumer friendliness while allowing
such occurrences as a phone call
on a Sunday at 8.00 am to sell you something
you almost assuredly will not want and, further, that when disputes arise,
industry
members will adjudicate on themselves in non-transparent dispute
resolution procedures.
There has also been significant criticism of the
consultation process in developing the ADMA Code. One of the failings of Codes
is
that there is no mandated requirement that they be developed with consumers
or consumer organisations.[10] In
the present case, ADMA applied to the Australian Competition and Consumer
Commission (ACCC) for authorisation of its Code on the
basis that its effects
may be anti-competitive (a typical problem of Codes). Having applied for
authorisation under s.88 of the Trade Practices Act 1974, the ACCC must
consult ‘interested parties’. It was this consultation, at the
eleventh hour, that saw consumer advocacy
organisations alerted to the problems
with the ADMA Code. If an industry that develops a Code decides not to apply for
authorisation
(and there is no requirement in the development of a Code to apply
for authorisation), it is possible that no consultation with a
consumer or
consumer organisation has taken place. This fundamental lack of accountability
and potential disregard for those affected
by Codes should be addressed. (It is
a further difficulty that there was also strong criticism of the ACCC’s
role in relation
to the ADMA
Code).[11]
The ADMA Code
shows us that in practice many of these suggested benefits of Codes are not
borne out, at least as far as the consumer
is concerned. This, it is suggested,
is very much a product of the flawed ideology that drives the development of
codes. Clearly,
the temptation to act with sheer self-interest is very high when
government offers business the opportunity to regulate fair trading
itself. As
has been observed:
We do not accept that, as a general rule, self-regulation as the only or principal form of consumer protection is effective or desirable ... it sets up the suppliers or producers of the commodity as judges in their own cause and makes it likely that the balance of any scheme of self-regulation will favour the suppliers rather than the consumers: such is human nature.[12]
It is
important to remember that the United Kingdom, which has a longer experience in
self-regulatory consumer protection, and Codes
of Conduct in particular, has
already re-examined the effectiveness of Codes and come to conclusions that
should have even the most
ardent supporters of market-based regulation thinking
again. The UK study found that industry by industry development had led to
variable standards between Codes, lack of consumer awareness of Codes and lack
of coverage of non-members (trends already apparent
in
Australia).[13] Coverage (or lack of
it) is a fundamental problem for Codes of Conduct. The problem that
self-regulatory Codes only work to regulate
the behaviour of association members
is all the more important when it is considered that it is generally the most
marginal of businesses
(who will mostly not be members of the Association
in question) that cause consumers the greatest of problems. Coverage can
also
be a flexible concept. A criticism levelled at the ADMA Code is that whilst
ADMA claimed it represented about 75-80% of the market
by sales
volume,[14] a large number of calls
did not result in sales. It has been suggested that ADMA could represent only
50% of the market (or less)
by volume of calls (which would be the proper
measure of the ADMA Code’s impact on
privacy).[15]
Knowing the
history of the UK self-regulatory experience, it would be quite irresponsible of
the Australian government to abandon
consumers and allow a proliferation of
self- interested Codes in place of proper government intervention to assist a
fair market
place.
Self-regulation has the potential to be an innovative and important part of
the public policy mix that ensures fair trading. Unfortunately,
the pursuit of
market-based outcomes is seeing inadequate Codes of Conduct develop, with the
approval of regulatory authorities,
in a way that winds back the many
protections gained for consumers over recent years. If this continues,
self-regulation will become
the government’s gift to those businesses
which, wearing the badge of a ‘Fair Trading Member’, will relish the
opportunity to continue, enshrined in a code, the sharpest of practices.
Ineffectual codes of conduct simply tell us what we already
know: the market
place can’t necessarily be trusted to protect consumers. What a pity it is
then that a century that saw the
development of fundamental rights to protect
consumers against the avarice and disregard of the market place, will be closed
with
a return to the rule of the market place.
References
[1] For a discussion of this
movement, see Asher, A., Going Global: A New Paradigm for Consumer
Protection, Amercian Council of Consumer Interests, March
1998.
[2] A statement by the (then)
Minister for Consumer Affairs, Truss, W., ‘Foreword’ in Department
of Industry, Science and
Tourism, Codes of Conduct — Policy
Framework, March 1998, p.1.
[3]
There is considerable confusion as to what self-regulation (as opposed, for
example, to co-regulation) means. An attempt to define
them is made in Codes
of Conduct: Policy Framework, Ref 2 above,
p.8.
[4] Goldring, Maher, McKeough,
Pearson, Consumer Protection Law, Federation Press, 1998,
p.4.
[5] Goldring and others,
above, p.11. The Federal Government’s ‘general presumption is that
competitive market forces deliver
greater choice and benefits to consumers
[Codes of Conduct: Policy Framework, Ref 2 above,
p.3]’.
[6] Goldring and
others, above, p.13.
[7] The (then)
Minister for Consumer Affairs, The Honourable Geoff Prosser, stated that:
‘Product Safety is a clear government
responsibility’ in Prosser,
G., ‘Keynote Address’ in Department of Industry, Science and
Tourism, Industry Codes of Conduct — The Way Forward, Proceedings
of a Symposium on Codes, p.8.
[8]
Australian Direct Marketing Association, Direct Marketing Code of
Practice, p.12. Christmas Day, Good Friday and Easter Sunday are
spared.
[9] Department of Industry,
Science and Tourism, Fair Trading Codes of Conduct — Why have them, how to
prepare them, 1998, p.1.
[10]
Although it is certainly suggested that ‘community participation in
developing a Code can improve its design and effectiveness’
in Fair
Trading Codes of Conduct — Why have them, how to prepare them, Note 9,
p.2. Community participation does not necessarily involve consumer advocacy
organisations. Such was the case for the ADMA
Code.
[11] This Brief does not
examine those issues. Greenleaf, G., and Waters, N., ‘Direct Marketing
Code of Conduct hits ACCC Snag’,
Privacy Law and Policy Reporter,
June 1999 discusses many of the
criticisms.
[12] Goldring and
others, above, p.13.
[13] UK
Office of Fair Trading, Raising Standards of Consumer Care: Progressing
Beyond Codes of Practice, February 1998. Goldring and others suggest that
‘despite some early enthusiasm [codes are] now generally regarded as a
dismal
failure’ Goldring and others, Ref 4 above,
p.12.
[14] Edwards, R.,
‘Direct Marketing Code of Practice’ in Department of Industry,
Science and Tourism, Industry Codes of Conduct — The Way Forward,
Proceedings of a Symposium on Codes at
47.
[15] Financial Services
Consumer Policy Centre, The Proposed Direct Marketing Code: The Death of
Privacy, A submission to the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission
under s.90 of the Trade Practices Act 1974, November 1988, p.14.
AustLII:
Copyright Policy
|
Disclaimers
|
Privacy Policy
|
Feedback
URL: http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/AltLawJl/1999/29.html