The torch has passed. A new paradigm is in the making.
What is left of the past is the faint reminder that the crimes of rich
and
powerful must be treated different by criminologists and jurists
alike. This common strain of thought is however not strong enough
to
provide any intellectual linkage between the two school of thoughts.
What we have then is two different criminological research
areas, each
equipped with its own set of concepts, theories, methodologies and
literature.[97]
Notes
[1]
The concept of white-collar crime was first introduced by Sutherland at the 1939 American Sociological meeting.
[2] See
Gilbert Geis (ed.), White-collar Criminals (New York: Atherton Press,
1968), p. 21. The first major treatment of Sutherland's
thesis is in
"White-collar Criminality," American Sociological Review 5 (February,
1940), pp. 1-12. A full treatment of his earthbreaking
work is to be
found in White-collar Crime ( New York, Dryden Press, 1949).
[3]
See ibid. White-collar Crime, p. 9.
[4] John
Braithwaite. “White-collar Crime.” Annual Review of
Sociology 11:1-25. (1985) Jack Katz. “The social movement
against
white-collar crime.” Criminology Review Yearbook 2:161-184.
(1980).
[5]
Sutherland’s concept of white-collar crime by focusing
exclusively on the social status of the “upper-class”
criminals
becomes an imprisoning conceptual framework to study other
from of organized crime hidden from public view. Susan P, Shapiro.
Thinking
about White-collar Crime: Matters of Conceptualization and
Research. (Washington, D.C.: GPO., 1980). See also Susan Shapiro.
“
Collaring the crime, not the criminal: Reconsidering the
concept of white-collar crime.” American Sociological Review
55:346-365,346
(1990).
[6] It
appears that Sutherland was not the only person who was concerned with
the powers and influences of the rich and powerful. "The
power elite is
composed of men whose positions enable them to transcend the ordinary
environments of ordinary men and women; they
are in position to make
decisions having major consequences... They occupy the strategic
command posts of the social structure, in
which are now centered the
effective means of power ..." See C. Wright Mills, The Power Elite (New
York: Oxford University Press,
1956), pp. 1-2.
[7]
The Atlantic Monthly 90 (January, 1907), pp. 44-55.
[8]
(New York: Longmans, Green and Co., 1935), pp. 152-158, p. 152.
[9] The
white-collar criminals achieved immunity from criminal prosecution for
their deviance as a result of two facts: (a) White-collars
crimes are
invisible crime. The public do not have the ability, capacity or the
information to monitor white-collar criminality.
(b) White-collar
criminals are powerful people. They are able to obstruct the course of
law and justice due to their position, powers,
connections, and
influence. Sutherland was instrumental in bringing white-collar crimes
to public light. It was up to the critical
criminologists (Quinney,
Turks) to observe that public knowledge of white-collar crimes alone is
not enough to control the rich and
powerful. Austin A. Turk,
“Prospect for Theories.” Journal of Criminal Law,
Criminology and Police Science. 55:454-461
(1964). (Richard Quinney,
“Crime in Political Perspective.” American Behavioral
Scientists. 8:19-22 (1964). Quinney,
Critique of Legal Order: Crime
Control in Capitalistic Society. (Boston, Little Brown, 1974). A shift
in theoretical perspective
and disciplinary paradigm is necessary to
deconstruct the social reality of deviance. In this way, Sutherland can
be viewed as laying
the necessary ground work for the critical
criminologists, years later. He facilitated the shift from positive
thinking to constructive
thinking to phenomenological thinking,
critical thinking and now post-modernist thinking about crime and
control. Richard Quinney
Criminology. (Boston: Little Brown, 1975), pp.
9-12.
[10]
See Henderson, Introduction to the Study of the Dependent, Defective
and Delinquent Classes, 2nd ed. (Boston: D.C. Heath, 1901).
For a brief
account of Sutherland's intellectual development, see generally Peter
Wickman and Timothy Dailey (eds.), White-collar
and Economic Crime
(Lexington Books, 1982), pp. 8-9.
[11]
Ibid. p. 8.
[12]
See Sutherland, "White-collar Criminality," op. cit.., note 1, pp. 11-12.
[13]
A survey of 100 leading scholars in the field of criminology regarded
Sutherland's work on white-collar crime as the fourth most
important
contribution made in the field. See White-collar and Economic Crime,
op. cit., note 4, p. 16. Not all scholars at the time
were equally
receptive to or impressed by Sutherland's work. Much debate was
generated about his initial conceptualization and definition
of
white-collar crime. As one scholar observed: "The concept has remained
unclear because criminologists have subsumed different
behavior under
the term. In addition, writers have varied on the amount of emphasis
given to the social status of the offender, have
employed different
meanings of occupational activity, and have lacked consistency in
designating the illegal nature of the offense."
See Richard Quinney,
"The Study of White-collar crime: toward a reorientation in theory and
practice," pp. 283-296 in G. Geis and
R.F. Meier (eds.) White-collar
Crime (rev. ed.) (New York: Free press, 1977). For a debate whether
administrative and civil violations
by corporations should be
considered as crimes, see Edwind H. Sutherland, "Is 'White-collar
Crime?" American Sociological Review
10 (April, 1945), pp. 132-139
("white-collar crime" is defined by its adverse social consequences and
not its convenient legal label)
and Paul W. Tappan, "Who is The
Criminal?" American Sociological Review, 12 (February, 1947), pp.
96-102 (criminals are those who
have been adjudicated by the courts to
have violated criminal law.) See also E. W. Burgess, "Comment,"
American Sociological Review
56 (1950) who argued that there is a
material difference between crimes arousing moral indignation
(traditional common law crime)
and those which do not excite public
condemnation (white-collar crime). pp. 32-4.
[14]
Vaughan, E. Diane "Recent development in white-collar crime theory and
research," in I.L. Barak-Glantz and R. Huff (eds.) The Mad,
The Bad,
and the Different (Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1981), p. 135.
[15]
See Frank B. Hartung, "White-Collar Offenses in the Wholesale Meat
Market Industry in Detroit," American Sociological Review 56 (1950),
pp. 25-34. Hartung's article is not a remarkable piece of research
viewed by today’s standard. However at that time it contributed
much in verifying Sutherland's earth breaking thesis by generating a
first of its kind empirical data. The paper reinforced Sutherland's
oft-repeated statement that white-collar crime is "true crime"
according to the "pure-theory school of law": The "pure-theory" school
argued that a crime is one that is proscribed and made punishable by
law. See Hans Kelsen, General Theory of Law and State (Cambridge:
Harvard University Press, 1945). The fact that the proscribed act is
not criminally processed does not detract from its inherent
criminality.
In a "Comment" following the article, Professor Burgress disagreed.
"There is no evidence that OPA violators conceived
themselves as
criminal or were so considered by the public." He observed that the
Emergency Price Control Act and the Second War
Powers Act made
otherwise innocent business transactions criminal overnight. He argued
that a crime is only a crime when it is sufficiently
apprehensible to
arouse public condemnation and social indignation, i.e. strong enough
to warrant the imposition of criminal penalty
as provided by the law.
Ibid. pp. 30-34. The imposition of criminal penalty itself does not
make an act criminal. The public condemnation
is the only litmus test.
The novel part of this debate is that there was a reversal of
traditional position: Burgess was accusing
Hartung to be too legalistic
while Hartung was accusing Burgress as too sociological. Another
noteworthy aspect of this article is
its definition of white-collar
crime as conducts of the business firm. However this operational
definition seemed to have been adopted
without much in-depth analysis
of its conceptual implications.
[16]
Ibid. p. 25.
[17]
Vilhelm Aubert, "What-Collar Crime and Social Structure," American Journal of Sociology 58 (November, 1952), pp. 263-271.
[18]
See Marshall B. Clinard, The Black Market: A Study of White-collar
Crime (N.Y.: Holt, 1952), "Criminological Theories of Violations
of
"Criminological Theories of Violations of Wartime Regulations,"
American Sociological Review, 11 (June, 1946), pp. 258-270.
[19]
Marshall Clinard, The Black Market (New York: Rinehart and Co., 1952) p. 127.
[20]
"In 1977, of 3,486 persons who were convicted of violations of the
price and rationing regulations, only 27 per cent received imprisonment
and fine. Of the total convicted, 46 per cent received only fine, and
28 per cent were placed on probation." Ibid. p. 261.
[21]
First, the theory did not satisfactory explain why some people who were
associated with OPA violators and were familiar with the
techniques of
violation did not become violators. Second, the theory viewed offender
in a unidimensional frame. Businessmen were
differentially exposed to
multiple associations and subject to divergent and conflicting role
expectations. What he learned from
the job might not be controlling of
his motivation and action. Third, the theory placed too much emphasis
on recent personality development
and not sufficient attention to
earlier personality formation. Finally the theory failed to account for
independent and original
in the development of criminal skills, habits
and motivations. Ibid. pp. 268-9.
[22]
Robert E. Lane, "Why Businessmen Violate the Law," 44 Journal of
Criminal Law, Criminology and Police Science 151-165 (1953). Lane was
interested in finding out "why do some businessmen violate these laws
while others do not?" (p. 151). Although talking
in terms of
businessmen, Lane's research focused on business firm behavior. Lane
was particularly interested in finding out how economics,
whether
"greed" or "need," promotes criminality? Whether ambiguity, ignorance
and incapacity affects compliance with the law? Whether
patterns of
violations are related to close associations between violators? Whether
personality and experience of the firm or its
management has an impact
on compliance?
[23]
Overall, the study suffered from a weakness in research design. The
methodology was not well discussed in the paper. There were apparently
no effort taken to make sure that the sample was representative and the
measures used conformed to exacting statistical requirements.
[24]
See Donald R. Cressey, "The Criminal Violation of Financial Trust,"
American Sociological Review 15 (December, 1950), pp. 738-743.
Cressey
wanted to understand why do some and not all people violate their
trust?
[25]
See Richard Quinney, "Occupational Structure and Criminal Behavior:
Prescription Violations By Retail Pharmacists," Social Problem,
11
(Fall, 1963). pp. 179-185, 179.
[26]
For example Geis has observed that Sutherland’s concept was vague
and shifted with context of use. See Gilber Geis. “White-collar
Crime: What is it?” In Kip Schlegel and David Weisburd (eds.),
White-collar Crime Reconsiered. (Boston: Northeastern University
Press,
1992) There is a substantial body of literature that is critical of the
concept. See e.g. Braithwaite (1985), Shapiro (1980,
1990), Michael
Levi. “Crsis? What crisis? Reactions to commercial fraud in
action in the United Kingdom.” Contemporary
Crises 11:2-7-221
(1987), Dwight C. Smith Jr. “Paragons, pariachs, and pirates: A
spectrum-based theory of enterprise." Crime
and Delinquent. 26:358-386
(1975).
[27]
See "The Study of White-Collar Crime: Toward a Re-orientation in Theory
and Research," in Gilbert Geis and Robert F. Meier, (eds.),
White-Collar Crime (N.Y.: Free Press, 1977), p. 285.
[28]
See Tappan, supra.
[29]
See note 12, supra.
[30]
See note 15 supra.
[31]
See Man, Crime and Society (N.Y.:Random House, 1962), p. 402.
[32]
See "Toward a Delineation of White-Collar Offenses," Sociological Inquiry
[32]
(1962), p. 171.
[33]
These pioneer scholars were responsible for drawing the intellectual
map of white-collar crime. In so doing they became a necessary
guide
and inevitable hindrance for generations of scholars to come.
Unwittingly, in opening up a new area of scientific inquiry these
pioneer researchers provided for its ultimate demise - original
conceptual definition and theoretical orientation has a tendency
of
outliving its utility in confining "sociological imagination." For the
cumulative nature of scientific work, see Merton, Social
Theory and
Social Structure (New York, Free Press, 1967) (3rd ed.) p. 25. For an
evocative essay on how the scientific enterprise
can stifle
"imagination." See Mills, "Sociological Imagination." For a discussion
of how limiting scientific paradigms can be see,
Thomas S. Khun, The
Structure of Scientific Revolutions (Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1962).
[34]
See From white-collar crime to organizational crime - the reconceptualization of a field, infra.
[35]
Lane was a notable exception. See note 17, supra. However he was not
able to capitalize his find in developing a research agenda
based
solely on corporate or organization deviance.
[36]
A scholar has described Sutherland's approach to the study of
white-collar crime "economic anthropomorphism," See Gilbert Geis,
"Toward
a Delineation of White-collar Offenses," Sociological Inquiry,
Vol. 32 (Spring, 1962), pp. 160-171.) See Geis (1992)
(“Sutherland
was most concerned with upper-echelon businessmen in
the service of their corporations...” (p. 35).
[37]
For an insightful look into how Sutherland's childhood and educational
experience influenced his outlook on life in general and views
of
white-collar crime in particular see Gilbert Geis and Colin Goff,
"Edwin H. Sutherland: A Biographical and Analytical Commentary."
In
White-collar and Economic Crime, op. cit., note 7. Sutherland was
brought up by a Nebraska minister in an rural area. (p. 5) Sutherland
was raised in a tradition of "dedication to service" and "taking the
side of the underprivileged." (p. 4) He inherited a rugged
individualism
of the old frontier from his father and was much against
entrenched interests and big business. His rural upbringing also made
him
suspicious of city-bred sophistication. (p. 5)
[38]
In this Sutherland and his followers were faulted for their missionary
zeal. Nor were their objectivity ever questioned. After all,
just like
generation X, he is the product of an era. He personalified the
thinking of the time as the time captured his thinking.
"The early
sociological scholars came together from a wide diversity of sources,
but few would miss the strong ministerial tone that
pervaded their
ranks. They were persons of evangelical bent who believed that they had
found the resolution of man's difficulties
in a moral fever buttressed
by the dictates and metaphors of science." See Geis, op. cit. note 2,
p. 2. Scholars do not live outside
their environment - cultural and
intellectual. Academics cannot be separated from the social milieu they
find themselves. The Americans
are a highly moralistic lot. Liberalism
has a been a tradition with, if not a birthmark of, American
intellectuals. The beginning
of the 19th centers saw the ascendancy of
the "new left" with its progressive mentality and anti-business,
anti-government social
agenda. These observations led one scholar to
observe: "The "new left" in politics and in the social sciences often
substituted moral
indignation for political analysis..." See generally
Anthony M. Platt, 2nd ed., The Child Savers (The University of Chicago
Press,
1977),p. xiii. For an observation of such similar tendency in
international-China studies, see Ezra P. Vogel, “ Contemporary
China Studies in North America,” paper presented at Thirtieth
Anniversary Conference: The Development of Contemporary, China
Studies,
The Universities Service Centre, The Chinese University of Hong Kong,
25 June, 1993, p. 5.
[39]
See Geis, op. cite note 2, p. 16.
[40]
Sutherland’s approach is followed by scores of criminal justice
scholars from community policing to zero tolerance of policing.
See Kam
C. Wong, “The Philosophy of Community Policing in China.”
Justice Quarterly (Forthcoming, 2001). Whether Sutherland
was aware of
it or not, as standard bearer of an emerging academic doctrine, he has
to define his concept and idea broad enough to
attract the attention of
many disaffected scholars who are not completely satisfied with the
standard conceptual construction and
theoretical development in the
field, i.e. positivistic and class based criminology, sufficient to
debunk the existing disciplinary
paradigm. As Mao of China once said,
“Revolution is not like going to a tea party.” Refinements
to ideas come after and
not before an intellectual war of ideas is won.
[41]
Sutherland was preoccupied with social and economic "status" of the
offender and its consequence on criminological research. This
was made
plain in his now controversial footnote: "Perhaps it should be repeated
that "white-collar" (upper) and "lower" classes
merely designate
persons of high- and low-socioeconomic status. Income and amount of
money involved in the crime are not the sole
criteria. Many persons of
"low" socio-economic status are "white-collar" criminals in the sense
that they are well dressed, well
educated, and have high income; but
"white-collar" as used in this paper means "respected," socially
accepted and approved," "looked
up to." Some people in this class may
not be well dressed or well educated or have high incomes, although the
"upper" classes usually
exceed the "lower" classes in these respects,
as well as social status." See Sutherland, "White-collar Criminality"
American Sociological
Review 5: 1-12 (Feb., 1940).
[42]
The inability to draw the distinction between corporation and its
personnel is no more apparent than in "Crime of Corporations,"
in
Albert Cohen, Alfred Lindersmith and Karl Schuessler (eds.), The
Sutherland Papers (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1956),
pp.
78-96. It is ironic that such distinction was not made. Sutherland's
original white-collar crime study was based on a tabulation
of the
crimes of seventy of the largest U.S. corporations. In his analysis he
constantly referred to corporation as violators.
[43]
See "Historical Developments" in Ch. 3 "Collective Responsibility and
Collective Punishment," in Hermann Mannheim, Group Problems
in Crime
and Punishment (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul Limited, 1955), pp. 44
ff. Both the moral precepts in the Bible and legal
principles in Roman
law were highly individualistic, but there are to be cultural
differences, see e.g. Sally Moore, "Legal liability
and evolutionary
interpretation: some aspects of strict liability, self-help and
collective responsibility," in Max Gluckman (ed.)
The Allocation of
Responsibility (Manchester University Press, 1972), pp. 51-107 (The
Kipsigis and Longo can appeal to fellow kinsman
for contribution to
settle blood debt) and historical aberrations, see H.G. Hanbury,
English Courts of Law (Oxford University Press,
1944), p. 28 (in
England, William the Conqueror established "murder-fine" holding the
hundred - a local unit of government - responsible
for the murder of a
Norman - to this Anglo-Saxon cultural norm.)
[44]
For the latest statement of the problem of methodological individualism
in social research, see James S. Coleman. Foundation of Social
Theory
(Harvard University Press, 1993), p. 5.
[45]
For an excellent account of progressive attitudes and practices, see
David Rothman, Conscience and Convenience (Little Brown and
Company,
1980), Ch. 2 "Individual Justice: The Progressive Design." pp. 43-81.
[46]
For an assessment of the availability of white-collar crime data see
Albert Reiss and Albert D. Biderman, Data Sources on White-Collar
Law
Breaking (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Justice, National
Institute of Justice, 1980). See White-collar and Economic Crime,
op.
cit.., note 4, p. xi. See Gilbert Geis and Ezra Stotland,
"Introduction," in White-collar Crime: Theory and Research (Beverly
Hills: Sage Publications, 1980), p. 10 for the reasons of the lack of
such accounting system. Some of the reasons are: lack of a
precise
definition of corporate-organization crime, lack of a comprehensive
scheme to standardize reporting, difficulty in obtaining
data from
different sources - multiple geographic, political and functional
jurisdiction governing one regulated act, victimless
and hidden nature
of white-collar crime and impossibility to objectively measure harm
done, e.g. trust. For the consequence of such
a lack of data set, see
American Bar Association, Section on Criminal Justice, Economic
Offenses (Washington, D.C.: American Bar
Association, 1977), p. 20.
[47]
See Ch. 1 "Point of Departure" in Daniel Katz and Robert Kahn, The
Social Psychology of Organizations (New Delhi: Wiley Eastern Private
Limited, 1966), pp. 1-13.
[48]
See "Criminals of The Upper world," op. cit., note 2, p. 152.
[49]
See Sutherland, "What is "White-collar Crime," Op. cit.., note 4, p. 8.
[50]
See generally Kuhlman, "Nature and Significance of Price fixing Rings,"
Antitrust Law and Economics Review 2: 69-81 (1969), Asche
and Seneca,
"Is Collusion Profitable?" The Review of Economic and Statistics 58:
1-12 1976)
[51]
The ability of the capitalist to shape political agenda and dictate
legal norms is first made explicit by Marx. The motivation to
control
the business environment through legal and political arena is well
argued by John K. Galbraith, The Industrial State (N.Y.:
Signet Books,
1967). The process whereby the corporations rise above the rule of law
is well documented in Abram Chayes, "The Modern
Corporation and The
Rule of Law," in Edward S. Mason (ed.), The Corporation in Modern
Society (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University
Press, 1959).
[52]
See Sutherland, "White-collar Criminality," op. cit.., note 11, p. 3.
As observed by Sherman: "The resources, technology, and even
the
incentive for committing many crimes are only to be found in formal
organizations. Industrial pollution, discriminatory employment
practices, price fixing, and fraudulent corporate financial reporting
are examples of crimes that only formal organizations are capable
of
committing." Lawrence W. Sherman, Scandal and Reform (Berkeley:
University of California Press, 1979), p. 3.
[53]
The full research report see Sutherland, White-collar Crime ( N.Y.: Dryer Press, 1949).
[54]
"Crime of Corporations," in Albert Cohen, Alfred Lindersmith and Karl
Schuessler (eds.), The Sutherland Papers (Bloomington: Indiana
University Press, 1956), pp. 78-96, 80.
[55]
Id. 90.
[56]
Id.
[57]
See literature review in Chapter one "Introduction and Review of the
Literature," in Katherine M. Jamieson, Corporate Crime and
Organizational
Processes (SUNY-Albany, 1989), unpublished dissertation.
[58]
See Morris, "Criminals of Upperworld," op. cit.., note 2.
[59]
Albert J. Reiss, Jr., "The Study of Deviant Behavior: Where the Action
Is," The Ohio Valley Sociologist, Vol. 32 (1966), pp. 1-2.
[60]
A.J. Reiss, Jr. "Organizational deviance," in M.D. Ermann and R.J.
Lundman (eds.) Corporate and Government Deviance (N.Y.: Oxford
University Press, 1978)
[61]
See E. Gross. "Organizational structure and organizational crime." Pp.
52-77 in G. Geis and E. Stoland (eds.) White-collar Crime:
Theory and
Research (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1980). See also Ronald Kramer.
"Corporate Crime: An Organizational Perspective," in
P. Wickerman and
T. Dailey (eds.) White-collar and Economic Crime (Lexington, MA:
Lexington Books, 1982), pp. 75-94. "The challenge
to criminologists,
therefore is clear: to develop empirically based explanations of
corporate decision making and illegal organizational
behavior" at an
organization level. p. 78 and Kiriesberg made clear that "effective
legal policy concerning corporate crime must
be found on an
understanding of the decision-making process underlying corporate
action." "Decisionmaking Models and the Control
of Corporate Crime" 85
Yale Law Journal 1091-1129, 1092 (1978).
[62]
See Laura Shill Schrager and James F. Short, Jr. "Toward a Sociology of
Organizational Crime." Social Problem 25 (June 1978) 410.
[63]
See Stanton Wheeler. "Trends and problems in the sociological study of
crime," Social Problem 23:525-33 (1976). Professor Stanton
Wheeler
addressed the Association in 1976. Following that Yale University
reviewed a generous $1 million dollar research grant for
the research
into white-collar crime. Since then the white-collar project has
generated a number of detailed field research in the
detection,
prosecution, defense and punishment of corporate criminals. Wheeler's
own contribution to understanding of organizational
crime is reported
in Wheeler and Rothman, " The Organization as Weapon in
White-collar-Crime," 80 Michigan Law Review 1403-26 (1982).
[64]
Needleman and Needleman, "Organizational Crime: Two Models of
Criminogenesis," Sociological Quarterly 20: 517-528 (1979); Clinard
and
Yeager, Corporate Crime (N.Y.: The Free Press, 1980); Clinard,
Corporate Ethics and Crime (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1983); Coleman,
"Law and Power: The Sherman Antitrust Act and its Enforcement in the
Petroleum Industry," Social Problems 32: 264-274 (1985); Braithwaite
and Fisse, "Varieties of Responsibilities and Organizational Crime,"
Law and Policy 7: 315-343 (1985); Vaughan, Controlling Unlawful
Organizational Behavior (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983);
Fisse and Braithwaite, The Impact of Publicity on Corporate
Offenders
(SUNY Press, 1983); Shapiro, Wayward Capitalists (Yale University
Press, 1984); Hawkins and Thomas (eds.), Enforcing Regulation
(Kluwer-Nijhoff, 1984).
[65]
This observation should help put to rest some of the sterile, but no
less contentious, academic debate of who set the agenda and
otherwise
control the work of the academically free - professionally insulated
and individually independent minded - scholars. The
academic
researchers, much like the Supreme Court Justices, have different roles
to play. As professionals they remain aloof from
the crowd. As
citizens, they are responsive and responsible to listen to the drum of
the populace. In the end, their work will reflect
the values and
concerns of the time - albeit ever so discreetly and surreptitious.
This, in the jargon of the academic arena, is
called being relevant.
[66]
For a superb journalistic account of the era, see Godfrey Hodgson, American in Our Time (Vintage Books, 1976).
[67]
See Mark Dowie, "Pinto Madness," Mother Jones September-October, 1977,
pp. 18-32; See also CBS News. "Is Your Car Safe?" 60 minutes,
Vol. 10,
no. 40. Broadcast of the CBS television network, Sunday, 11 June 1978.
[68]
See Robert Sherill, "The Case Against the Oil Companies," October 14, 1979, New York Times Magazine.
[69]
See Michael H. Brown, "Love Canal and the Poising of America," in Mark
Green and Robert Massie, Jr. (eds.), The Big Business Reader
(N.Y.:
Pilgrim Press, 1980),
[70]
See Report of the Commission to Investigate Allegations of Police
Corruption and the City's Anti-Corruption Procedures (Knapp
Commission),
1972.
[71]
See Nelson, Cointelpro: The FBI Secret War on Political Freedom (N.Y.:
Random House, 1976), FBI Jackson, "FBI Admits It Opened Mail
in Eight
Cities in Illegal Program Parallel to that of CIA," L.A. Times, October
2, 1975.
[72]
See Carl Bernstein and Bob Woodward, All The President's Men (New York: Warner Publishing, 1974.
[73]
David Garland observed in Punishment and Modern Society (Chicago
University Press, 1990) that "sources of penal change and the
determinants
of penal form are located not just in penological
reasoning or economic interest, or strategic of power, but in the
configurations
of value, meaning, and emotion which we call 'culture."
[74]
See Ralph Nader, Unsafe at Any Speed (New York, Grossman: 1965). The
book that start of the consumer movement against big business.
[75]
See Mark Green, Ralph Nader and Joel Seligman, Taming the Giant Corporation (1976).
[76]
Marshall B. Clinard and Peter C. Yeager, "Corporate Crime: Issues in Research," Criminology 16:255-272 (1978).
[77]
The renewed in interest in white-collar crime in 1970-80, particular
those perpetrated by big, impersonal organizations, is thus
not
accidental.
[78]
See e.g. Conference on White-collar Crime in 1974 by Simon Dinitz,
Herbert Edelhertz and John Conrad. See Diane C. Vaughan, Crime
Between
Organization (Ph.D. dissertation, Ohio State University, 1979), Chapter
II, note 47, p. 71. Conference on White-collar and
Economic Crime:
Trends and Problems in Research and Policy: Multidisciplinary and Cross
National Perspectives, held at SUNY College
of Arts and Science,
Postdam, New York, 7-9 February, 1980. Panels were organized at
academic conferences. See M. David Ermann and
Richard J. Lundman,
"Deviant Acts by Complex Organizations: Deviant and Social Control at
the Organizational Level of Analysis,"
paper presented at the Annual
Meeting of the American Sociological Association, San Francisco, 1975;
James Frey, "Some General Observations
on Deviant Behavior by
Organizations," paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American
Sociological Association, Chicago, 1977
and Laura Shill Schrager and
James F. Short, Jr., "Toward a Definition of Organizational Crime,"
paper presented at the Annual Meeting
of the American Sociological
Association," Chicago, 1977.
[79]
The increase funding to the academia was part of a larger state and
national effort to fight white-collar crime. The National District
Attorneys' Association joined force with the Academy for Contemporary
Problems (Columbus, Ohio) to conduct research "which would
both enhance
prosecution capabilities in the area of economic crime and also give
new impetus to criminological research into his
area." Herbert
Edelhertz, "National District Attorneys' Association Demonstration
Project: Economic Crime," in Diane Vaughan (ed.).
Monograph on Economic
Crime (Columbus Ohio, 1974), Unpublished. LEAA funding was made
available for law enforcement (special units
for prosecution of
white-collar crime in selected cities across the United States) and
research projects (e.g. 5 year research program
at Yale as "the
beginning of a substantial and increasing commitment on the federal
level to response to white-collar crime and corruption."
See Bernard
Auchter, "Federal Level Research and Demonstration in White-collar
Crime Control: Efforts of the Law Enforcement Assistant
Administration," paper presented at American Society of Criminology,
Annual Meeting, Dallas Texas, November 8-12, 1978.
[80]
See Diane C. Vaughan, Crime Between Organizations (PHD thesis: Ohio State University, 1979)., pp. 55-56.
[81]
Herbert Edelhertz redefined white-collar crime as economic crime: "An
illegal act or series of acts committed by concealment or guile,
to
obtain money or property, to avoid the payment or loss of money of
property, or to obtain business or personal advantage." The
Nature,
Impact and Prosecution of White-collar Crime, National Institute of Law
Enforcement and Criminal Justice, U.S. Department
of Justice, Law
Enforcement Assistance Administration, 1970, p. 3. Note this definition
emphasize on the nature of the offense instead
of the status of the
offender. In so doing, it captures much of Sutherland's concern, i.e.
people obtaining economic advantage by
"concealment and guile" (usually
by breach of trust) without being faithful to his original definition,
that of "crime committed
by a person of respectability and high social
status."
[82]
It is difficult to trace intellectual history. Literal citations,
personal acknowledgment and biographic reconstruction provide some
of
the sources to track some of the ideas. Most of the time they are
incomplete to grasp fully the inter-connectedness of a stock
of ideas,
through time and across discipline. Most ideas are inter-related
directly in some way, either logically or temporally;
making it easy to
observe the connection. However, when concepts and ideas are indirectly
related, when they are tangentially interconnected,
when they are
separated in space and time and when the an idea belong to stock of
ideas which provides needed stimulation and necessary
context for the
development of other ideas (for each other, in parallel or later), much
is left to speculation and conjecture. Abstract
ideas do exhibit
continuity and inter-dependency. For an enlightening discussion on
evolution of ideas, see Merton, "On The History
and Systematics of
Sociological Theory," in Social Theory and Social Structure (New York:
Free Press, 1968), pp. 1-39.
[83]
It is of interest to note, whether it is in politics, law or academic
world, the first step to debunk a traditional ideology, established
precedent or dominant paradigm is not by challenging its legitimacy
completely or disagreeing with it totally but to acknowledge
its
dominance and merits and seek only to modify it in part - textually,
spiritually or directionally. Such a strategy allow the
new ideas to
gain legitimacy and foothold. To attempt a frontal attack on existing
ideas is much like attempting revolution in the
face of a repressive
regime; it is suicidal.
[84]
See Richard Quinney, "The Study of White-Collar Crime: Toward a
Re-orientation in Theory and Research," in Gilbert Deis and Robert
F.
Meier, (eds.), White-Collar Crime (New York: Free Press, 1977), p. 285.
[85]
See Marshall B. Clinard, The Black Market (New York: Rinehart and Co,. Inc. 1952), p. 127.
[86]
Newman focused on violator's occupational role more so than his social
status in classifying white-collar criminal. Donald J. Newman,
"White-Collar Crime: An Overview and Analysis" Ibid. p. 52,
[87]
Defining white-collar crime by social status is controversial: it is
very nebulous to behold, impossible to articulate and too subjective
and value laden to sustain any critical analysis.
[88]
See Lawrence W. Sherman, Scandal and Reform (Berkeley: University of California press, 1978), p. 6.
[89]
See Stone, Where the Law Ends (N.Y.: Harper and Row, 1980), p. 50
(examining the relationship between corporate organizational structure
and informational flow); Clinard and Yeager (1980), supra, p. 131
(examining the relationship between market power and presence of
violations among manufacturing corporations); Vaughan (1983) (examining
the relationship between exernal environmental factors and
internal
corporate behavior)
[90]
Neal Shover, "Defining Organizational Crime," in M. David Ermann and
Richard J. Lundman (eds.), Corporate and Governmental Deviance:
Problems of Organizational Behavior in Contemporary Society (New York:
Oxford, 1978), pp. 28-36.
[91]
These critical distinctions in the study of organizational crime are
made explicit in Sherman's definitive study on control of deviant
organization. See Scandal and Reform.
[92]
See Ermann and Lundman, Organizational Deviance (1981), cited in Diane
Vaughan, Crime Between Organizations (Ph.D. Thesis: Ohio State
University, 1979), p. 61.
[93]
See Lawrence Sherman, Scandal and Reform (Berkeley, University of California Press, 1978).
[94]
See ibid. p. 6.
[95]
See ibid. pp. 7-15.
[96]
See ibid. p. 13.
[97]
An examination of Sherman's work on deviant organizations, Chapter 1
"Deviant Organizations," in Scandal and Reform, op. cit.., showed
that
there is only one reference (out of 46 footnotes) to a major
white-collar crime work, that of Sutherland's White-collar Crime
(1949). It was cited as "first sociological discussion of deviant
organizations." See ibid. footnote 1.