[Home] [Help] [Databases] [WorldLII] [Feedback] | ||
Murdoch University Electronic Journal of Law |
From White-Collar Crime to Organizational Crime: An Intellectual History
Kam C Wong
University of Wisconsin Oshkosh
Contents
First, our national history, political heritage, religious cult, economic theory and constitutional tradition are all bound up with the notion of atomistic individualism. Indeed the whole western civilization has put the individual in the center stage of thinking, acting and theorizing. More particularly, Anglo-American criminal law has been primarily concerned with individual culpability and not group responsibility. Jurisprudential thoughts likewise did not contemplate nor favor the punishment of group, collectives or organization. The criminal law made few provisions for the punishment of collectives, group and organization.[43]
Second, the study of crime and delinquency has always been interested in measuring, explaining, deterring and treating individual failures. The unit of analysis of extant criminological researches has been the individual. The question most consistently raised was also of the individual kind: why does a person commit crime? How can he be deterred? What can be done to reform him? In what way can be made to pay for his crime? Explanation of criminality tends to be of a classical (e.g. Bentham) or psychological (e.g. Beccaria) bent. Even when a macro theory was occasionally used to explain crime e.g. "ecological theory" of Shaw and Mckay, the focus was still on how socio-economic-political-cultural forces impact on the individual and his behavior. There were a number of reasons accounting for this trend: p>
Third, the study of organization as a sociological field has not come of age. Organizational study was then a young discipline yet to make its mark. Viewing the organization as having a separate identity and existence apart from its constituency required a whole new way of thinking; a paradigmatic shift yet to materialized.[47] The study of organization required huge resources and specialized skills (accounting, economics, criminal, administrative and business law), which was not in existence.
Individual acts and organizational acts are not one and the same. Innocent individual's acts may be considered illegal when the broader organizational goal, purpose and context are taken into account. Thus, individual innocent acts may become illegal when they are orchestrated to fulfill the illegitimate objectives of an organization as a unit whole. Likewise, illegal acts of the individual may or may not be attributed to the organization depending on the nexus between the individual's act and the organization's complicity in the act, e.g. by promoting, condoning or ratifying the act.
The personal motive, intention and disposition of the individual are no longer critical in the understanding of organizational crime. The organizational goal, structure and process become important.
[1] The concept of white-collar crime was first introduced by Sutherland at the 1939 American Sociological meeting.
[2] See Gilbert Geis (ed.), White-collar Criminals (New York: Atherton Press, 1968), p. 21. The first major treatment of Sutherland's thesis is in "White-collar Criminality," American Sociological Review 5 (February, 1940), pp. 1-12. A full treatment of his earthbreaking work is to be found in White-collar Crime ( New York, Dryden Press, 1949).
[3] See ibid. White-collar Crime, p. 9.
[4] John Braithwaite. “White-collar Crime.” Annual Review of Sociology 11:1-25. (1985) Jack Katz. “The social movement against white-collar crime.” Criminology Review Yearbook 2:161-184. (1980).
[5] Sutherland’s concept of white-collar crime by focusing exclusively on the social status of the “upper-class” criminals becomes an imprisoning conceptual framework to study other from of organized crime hidden from public view. Susan P, Shapiro. Thinking about White-collar Crime: Matters of Conceptualization and Research. (Washington, D.C.: GPO., 1980). See also Susan Shapiro. “ Collaring the crime, not the criminal: Reconsidering the concept of white-collar crime.” American Sociological Review 55:346-365,346 (1990).
[6] It appears that Sutherland was not the only person who was concerned with the powers and influences of the rich and powerful. "The power elite is composed of men whose positions enable them to transcend the ordinary environments of ordinary men and women; they are in position to make decisions having major consequences... They occupy the strategic command posts of the social structure, in which are now centered the effective means of power ..." See C. Wright Mills, The Power Elite (New York: Oxford University Press, 1956), pp. 1-2.
[7] The Atlantic Monthly 90 (January, 1907), pp. 44-55.
[8] (New York: Longmans, Green and Co., 1935), pp. 152-158, p. 152.
[9] The white-collar criminals achieved immunity from criminal prosecution for their deviance as a result of two facts: (a) White-collars crimes are invisible crime. The public do not have the ability, capacity or the information to monitor white-collar criminality. (b) White-collar criminals are powerful people. They are able to obstruct the course of law and justice due to their position, powers, connections, and influence. Sutherland was instrumental in bringing white-collar crimes to public light. It was up to the critical criminologists (Quinney, Turks) to observe that public knowledge of white-collar crimes alone is not enough to control the rich and powerful. Austin A. Turk, “Prospect for Theories.” Journal of Criminal Law, Criminology and Police Science. 55:454-461 (1964). (Richard Quinney, “Crime in Political Perspective.” American Behavioral Scientists. 8:19-22 (1964). Quinney, Critique of Legal Order: Crime Control in Capitalistic Society. (Boston, Little Brown, 1974). A shift in theoretical perspective and disciplinary paradigm is necessary to deconstruct the social reality of deviance. In this way, Sutherland can be viewed as laying the necessary ground work for the critical criminologists, years later. He facilitated the shift from positive thinking to constructive thinking to phenomenological thinking, critical thinking and now post-modernist thinking about crime and control. Richard Quinney Criminology. (Boston: Little Brown, 1975), pp. 9-12.
[10] See Henderson, Introduction to the Study of the Dependent, Defective and Delinquent Classes, 2nd ed. (Boston: D.C. Heath, 1901). For a brief account of Sutherland's intellectual development, see generally Peter Wickman and Timothy Dailey (eds.), White-collar and Economic Crime (Lexington Books, 1982), pp. 8-9.
[11] Ibid. p. 8.
[12] See Sutherland, "White-collar Criminality," op. cit.., note 1, pp. 11-12.
[13] A survey of 100 leading scholars in the field of criminology regarded Sutherland's work on white-collar crime as the fourth most important contribution made in the field. See White-collar and Economic Crime, op. cit., note 4, p. 16. Not all scholars at the time were equally receptive to or impressed by Sutherland's work. Much debate was generated about his initial conceptualization and definition of white-collar crime. As one scholar observed: "The concept has remained unclear because criminologists have subsumed different behavior under the term. In addition, writers have varied on the amount of emphasis given to the social status of the offender, have employed different meanings of occupational activity, and have lacked consistency in designating the illegal nature of the offense." See Richard Quinney, "The Study of White-collar crime: toward a reorientation in theory and practice," pp. 283-296 in G. Geis and R.F. Meier (eds.) White-collar Crime (rev. ed.) (New York: Free press, 1977). For a debate whether administrative and civil violations by corporations should be considered as crimes, see Edwind H. Sutherland, "Is 'White-collar Crime?" American Sociological Review 10 (April, 1945), pp. 132-139 ("white-collar crime" is defined by its adverse social consequences and not its convenient legal label) and Paul W. Tappan, "Who is The Criminal?" American Sociological Review, 12 (February, 1947), pp. 96-102 (criminals are those who have been adjudicated by the courts to have violated criminal law.) See also E. W. Burgess, "Comment," American Sociological Review 56 (1950) who argued that there is a material difference between crimes arousing moral indignation (traditional common law crime) and those which do not excite public condemnation (white-collar crime). pp. 32-4.
[14] Vaughan, E. Diane "Recent development in white-collar crime theory and research," in I.L. Barak-Glantz and R. Huff (eds.) The Mad, The Bad, and the Different (Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1981), p. 135.
[15] See Frank B. Hartung, "White-Collar Offenses in the Wholesale Meat Market Industry in Detroit," American Sociological Review 56 (1950), pp. 25-34. Hartung's article is not a remarkable piece of research viewed by today’s standard. However at that time it contributed much in verifying Sutherland's earth breaking thesis by generating a first of its kind empirical data. The paper reinforced Sutherland's oft-repeated statement that white-collar crime is "true crime" according to the "pure-theory school of law": The "pure-theory" school argued that a crime is one that is proscribed and made punishable by law. See Hans Kelsen, General Theory of Law and State (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1945). The fact that the proscribed act is not criminally processed does not detract from its inherent criminality. In a "Comment" following the article, Professor Burgress disagreed. "There is no evidence that OPA violators conceived themselves as criminal or were so considered by the public." He observed that the Emergency Price Control Act and the Second War Powers Act made otherwise innocent business transactions criminal overnight. He argued that a crime is only a crime when it is sufficiently apprehensible to arouse public condemnation and social indignation, i.e. strong enough to warrant the imposition of criminal penalty as provided by the law. Ibid. pp. 30-34. The imposition of criminal penalty itself does not make an act criminal. The public condemnation is the only litmus test. The novel part of this debate is that there was a reversal of traditional position: Burgess was accusing Hartung to be too legalistic while Hartung was accusing Burgress as too sociological. Another noteworthy aspect of this article is its definition of white-collar crime as conducts of the business firm. However this operational definition seemed to have been adopted without much in-depth analysis of its conceptual implications.
[16] Ibid. p. 25.
[17] Vilhelm Aubert, "What-Collar Crime and Social Structure," American Journal of Sociology 58 (November, 1952), pp. 263-271.
[18] See Marshall B. Clinard, The Black Market: A Study of White-collar Crime (N.Y.: Holt, 1952), "Criminological Theories of Violations of "Criminological Theories of Violations of Wartime Regulations," American Sociological Review, 11 (June, 1946), pp. 258-270.
[19] Marshall Clinard, The Black Market (New York: Rinehart and Co., 1952) p. 127.
[20] "In 1977, of 3,486 persons who were convicted of violations of the price and rationing regulations, only 27 per cent received imprisonment and fine. Of the total convicted, 46 per cent received only fine, and 28 per cent were placed on probation." Ibid. p. 261.
[21] First, the theory did not satisfactory explain why some people who were associated with OPA violators and were familiar with the techniques of violation did not become violators. Second, the theory viewed offender in a unidimensional frame. Businessmen were differentially exposed to multiple associations and subject to divergent and conflicting role expectations. What he learned from the job might not be controlling of his motivation and action. Third, the theory placed too much emphasis on recent personality development and not sufficient attention to earlier personality formation. Finally the theory failed to account for independent and original in the development of criminal skills, habits and motivations. Ibid. pp. 268-9.
[22] Robert E. Lane, "Why Businessmen Violate the Law," 44 Journal of Criminal Law, Criminology and Police Science 151-165 (1953). Lane was interested in finding out "why do some businessmen violate these laws while others do not?" (p. 151). Although talking in terms of businessmen, Lane's research focused on business firm behavior. Lane was particularly interested in finding out how economics, whether "greed" or "need," promotes criminality? Whether ambiguity, ignorance and incapacity affects compliance with the law? Whether patterns of violations are related to close associations between violators? Whether personality and experience of the firm or its management has an impact on compliance?
[23] Overall, the study suffered from a weakness in research design. The methodology was not well discussed in the paper. There were apparently no effort taken to make sure that the sample was representative and the measures used conformed to exacting statistical requirements.
[24] See Donald R. Cressey, "The Criminal Violation of Financial Trust," American Sociological Review 15 (December, 1950), pp. 738-743. Cressey wanted to understand why do some and not all people violate their trust?
[25] See Richard Quinney, "Occupational Structure and Criminal Behavior: Prescription Violations By Retail Pharmacists," Social Problem, 11 (Fall, 1963). pp. 179-185, 179.
[26] For example Geis has observed that Sutherland’s concept was vague and shifted with context of use. See Gilber Geis. “White-collar Crime: What is it?” In Kip Schlegel and David Weisburd (eds.), White-collar Crime Reconsiered. (Boston: Northeastern University Press, 1992) There is a substantial body of literature that is critical of the concept. See e.g. Braithwaite (1985), Shapiro (1980, 1990), Michael Levi. “Crsis? What crisis? Reactions to commercial fraud in action in the United Kingdom.” Contemporary Crises 11:2-7-221 (1987), Dwight C. Smith Jr. “Paragons, pariachs, and pirates: A spectrum-based theory of enterprise." Crime and Delinquent. 26:358-386 (1975).
[27] See "The Study of White-Collar Crime: Toward a Re-orientation in Theory and Research," in Gilbert Geis and Robert F. Meier, (eds.), White-Collar Crime (N.Y.: Free Press, 1977), p. 285.
[28] See Tappan, supra.
[29] See note 12, supra.
[30] See note 15 supra.
[31] See Man, Crime and Society (N.Y.:Random House, 1962), p. 402.
[32] See "Toward a Delineation of White-Collar Offenses," Sociological Inquiry
[32] (1962), p. 171.
[33] These pioneer scholars were responsible for drawing the intellectual map of white-collar crime. In so doing they became a necessary guide and inevitable hindrance for generations of scholars to come. Unwittingly, in opening up a new area of scientific inquiry these pioneer researchers provided for its ultimate demise - original conceptual definition and theoretical orientation has a tendency of outliving its utility in confining "sociological imagination." For the cumulative nature of scientific work, see Merton, Social Theory and Social Structure (New York, Free Press, 1967) (3rd ed.) p. 25. For an evocative essay on how the scientific enterprise can stifle "imagination." See Mills, "Sociological Imagination." For a discussion of how limiting scientific paradigms can be see, Thomas S. Khun, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962).
[34] See From white-collar crime to organizational crime - the reconceptualization of a field, infra.
[35] Lane was a notable exception. See note 17, supra. However he was not able to capitalize his find in developing a research agenda based solely on corporate or organization deviance.
[36] A scholar has described Sutherland's approach to the study of white-collar crime "economic anthropomorphism," See Gilbert Geis, "Toward a Delineation of White-collar Offenses," Sociological Inquiry, Vol. 32 (Spring, 1962), pp. 160-171.) See Geis (1992) (“Sutherland was most concerned with upper-echelon businessmen in the service of their corporations...” (p. 35).
[37] For an insightful look into how Sutherland's childhood and educational experience influenced his outlook on life in general and views of white-collar crime in particular see Gilbert Geis and Colin Goff, "Edwin H. Sutherland: A Biographical and Analytical Commentary." In White-collar and Economic Crime, op. cit., note 7. Sutherland was brought up by a Nebraska minister in an rural area. (p. 5) Sutherland was raised in a tradition of "dedication to service" and "taking the side of the underprivileged." (p. 4) He inherited a rugged individualism of the old frontier from his father and was much against entrenched interests and big business. His rural upbringing also made him suspicious of city-bred sophistication. (p. 5)
[38] In this Sutherland and his followers were faulted for their missionary zeal. Nor were their objectivity ever questioned. After all, just like generation X, he is the product of an era. He personalified the thinking of the time as the time captured his thinking. "The early sociological scholars came together from a wide diversity of sources, but few would miss the strong ministerial tone that pervaded their ranks. They were persons of evangelical bent who believed that they had found the resolution of man's difficulties in a moral fever buttressed by the dictates and metaphors of science." See Geis, op. cit. note 2, p. 2. Scholars do not live outside their environment - cultural and intellectual. Academics cannot be separated from the social milieu they find themselves. The Americans are a highly moralistic lot. Liberalism has a been a tradition with, if not a birthmark of, American intellectuals. The beginning of the 19th centers saw the ascendancy of the "new left" with its progressive mentality and anti-business, anti-government social agenda. These observations led one scholar to observe: "The "new left" in politics and in the social sciences often substituted moral indignation for political analysis..." See generally Anthony M. Platt, 2nd ed., The Child Savers (The University of Chicago Press, 1977),p. xiii. For an observation of such similar tendency in international-China studies, see Ezra P. Vogel, “ Contemporary China Studies in North America,” paper presented at Thirtieth Anniversary Conference: The Development of Contemporary, China Studies, The Universities Service Centre, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, 25 June, 1993, p. 5.
[39] See Geis, op. cite note 2, p. 16.
[40] Sutherland’s approach is followed by scores of criminal justice scholars from community policing to zero tolerance of policing. See Kam C. Wong, “The Philosophy of Community Policing in China.” Justice Quarterly (Forthcoming, 2001). Whether Sutherland was aware of it or not, as standard bearer of an emerging academic doctrine, he has to define his concept and idea broad enough to attract the attention of many disaffected scholars who are not completely satisfied with the standard conceptual construction and theoretical development in the field, i.e. positivistic and class based criminology, sufficient to debunk the existing disciplinary paradigm. As Mao of China once said, “Revolution is not like going to a tea party.” Refinements to ideas come after and not before an intellectual war of ideas is won.
[41] Sutherland was preoccupied with social and economic "status" of the offender and its consequence on criminological research. This was made plain in his now controversial footnote: "Perhaps it should be repeated that "white-collar" (upper) and "lower" classes merely designate persons of high- and low-socioeconomic status. Income and amount of money involved in the crime are not the sole criteria. Many persons of "low" socio-economic status are "white-collar" criminals in the sense that they are well dressed, well educated, and have high income; but "white-collar" as used in this paper means "respected," socially accepted and approved," "looked up to." Some people in this class may not be well dressed or well educated or have high incomes, although the "upper" classes usually exceed the "lower" classes in these respects, as well as social status." See Sutherland, "White-collar Criminality" American Sociological Review 5: 1-12 (Feb., 1940).
[42] The inability to draw the distinction between corporation and its personnel is no more apparent than in "Crime of Corporations," in Albert Cohen, Alfred Lindersmith and Karl Schuessler (eds.), The Sutherland Papers (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1956), pp. 78-96. It is ironic that such distinction was not made. Sutherland's original white-collar crime study was based on a tabulation of the crimes of seventy of the largest U.S. corporations. In his analysis he constantly referred to corporation as violators.
[43] See "Historical Developments" in Ch. 3 "Collective Responsibility and Collective Punishment," in Hermann Mannheim, Group Problems in Crime and Punishment (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul Limited, 1955), pp. 44 ff. Both the moral precepts in the Bible and legal principles in Roman law were highly individualistic, but there are to be cultural differences, see e.g. Sally Moore, "Legal liability and evolutionary interpretation: some aspects of strict liability, self-help and collective responsibility," in Max Gluckman (ed.) The Allocation of Responsibility (Manchester University Press, 1972), pp. 51-107 (The Kipsigis and Longo can appeal to fellow kinsman for contribution to settle blood debt) and historical aberrations, see H.G. Hanbury, English Courts of Law (Oxford University Press, 1944), p. 28 (in England, William the Conqueror established "murder-fine" holding the hundred - a local unit of government - responsible for the murder of a Norman - to this Anglo-Saxon cultural norm.)
[44] For the latest statement of the problem of methodological individualism in social research, see James S. Coleman. Foundation of Social Theory (Harvard University Press, 1993), p. 5.
[45] For an excellent account of progressive attitudes and practices, see David Rothman, Conscience and Convenience (Little Brown and Company, 1980), Ch. 2 "Individual Justice: The Progressive Design." pp. 43-81.
[46] For an assessment of the availability of white-collar crime data see Albert Reiss and Albert D. Biderman, Data Sources on White-Collar Law Breaking (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Justice, National Institute of Justice, 1980). See White-collar and Economic Crime, op. cit.., note 4, p. xi. See Gilbert Geis and Ezra Stotland, "Introduction," in White-collar Crime: Theory and Research (Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1980), p. 10 for the reasons of the lack of such accounting system. Some of the reasons are: lack of a precise definition of corporate-organization crime, lack of a comprehensive scheme to standardize reporting, difficulty in obtaining data from different sources - multiple geographic, political and functional jurisdiction governing one regulated act, victimless and hidden nature of white-collar crime and impossibility to objectively measure harm done, e.g. trust. For the consequence of such a lack of data set, see American Bar Association, Section on Criminal Justice, Economic Offenses (Washington, D.C.: American Bar Association, 1977), p. 20.
[47] See Ch. 1 "Point of Departure" in Daniel Katz and Robert Kahn, The Social Psychology of Organizations (New Delhi: Wiley Eastern Private Limited, 1966), pp. 1-13.
[48] See "Criminals of The Upper world," op. cit., note 2, p. 152.
[49] See Sutherland, "What is "White-collar Crime," Op. cit.., note 4, p. 8.
[50] See generally Kuhlman, "Nature and Significance of Price fixing Rings," Antitrust Law and Economics Review 2: 69-81 (1969), Asche and Seneca, "Is Collusion Profitable?" The Review of Economic and Statistics 58: 1-12 1976)
[51] The ability of the capitalist to shape political agenda and dictate legal norms is first made explicit by Marx. The motivation to control the business environment through legal and political arena is well argued by John K. Galbraith, The Industrial State (N.Y.: Signet Books, 1967). The process whereby the corporations rise above the rule of law is well documented in Abram Chayes, "The Modern Corporation and The Rule of Law," in Edward S. Mason (ed.), The Corporation in Modern Society (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1959).
[52] See Sutherland, "White-collar Criminality," op. cit.., note 11, p. 3. As observed by Sherman: "The resources, technology, and even the incentive for committing many crimes are only to be found in formal organizations. Industrial pollution, discriminatory employment practices, price fixing, and fraudulent corporate financial reporting are examples of crimes that only formal organizations are capable of committing." Lawrence W. Sherman, Scandal and Reform (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1979), p. 3.
[53] The full research report see Sutherland, White-collar Crime ( N.Y.: Dryer Press, 1949).
[54] "Crime of Corporations," in Albert Cohen, Alfred Lindersmith and Karl Schuessler (eds.), The Sutherland Papers (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1956), pp. 78-96, 80.
[55] Id. 90.
[56] Id.
[57] See literature review in Chapter one "Introduction and Review of the Literature," in Katherine M. Jamieson, Corporate Crime and Organizational Processes (SUNY-Albany, 1989), unpublished dissertation.
[58] See Morris, "Criminals of Upperworld," op. cit.., note 2.
[59] Albert J. Reiss, Jr., "The Study of Deviant Behavior: Where the Action Is," The Ohio Valley Sociologist, Vol. 32 (1966), pp. 1-2.
[60] A.J. Reiss, Jr. "Organizational deviance," in M.D. Ermann and R.J. Lundman (eds.) Corporate and Government Deviance (N.Y.: Oxford University Press, 1978)
[61] See E. Gross. "Organizational structure and organizational crime." Pp. 52-77 in G. Geis and E. Stoland (eds.) White-collar Crime: Theory and Research (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1980). See also Ronald Kramer. "Corporate Crime: An Organizational Perspective," in P. Wickerman and T. Dailey (eds.) White-collar and Economic Crime (Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 1982), pp. 75-94. "The challenge to criminologists, therefore is clear: to develop empirically based explanations of corporate decision making and illegal organizational behavior" at an organization level. p. 78 and Kiriesberg made clear that "effective legal policy concerning corporate crime must be found on an understanding of the decision-making process underlying corporate action." "Decisionmaking Models and the Control of Corporate Crime" 85 Yale Law Journal 1091-1129, 1092 (1978).
[62] See Laura Shill Schrager and James F. Short, Jr. "Toward a Sociology of Organizational Crime." Social Problem 25 (June 1978) 410.
[63] See Stanton Wheeler. "Trends and problems in the sociological study of crime," Social Problem 23:525-33 (1976). Professor Stanton Wheeler addressed the Association in 1976. Following that Yale University reviewed a generous $1 million dollar research grant for the research into white-collar crime. Since then the white-collar project has generated a number of detailed field research in the detection, prosecution, defense and punishment of corporate criminals. Wheeler's own contribution to understanding of organizational crime is reported in Wheeler and Rothman, " The Organization as Weapon in White-collar-Crime," 80 Michigan Law Review 1403-26 (1982).
[64] Needleman and Needleman, "Organizational Crime: Two Models of Criminogenesis," Sociological Quarterly 20: 517-528 (1979); Clinard and Yeager, Corporate Crime (N.Y.: The Free Press, 1980); Clinard, Corporate Ethics and Crime (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1983); Coleman, "Law and Power: The Sherman Antitrust Act and its Enforcement in the Petroleum Industry," Social Problems 32: 264-274 (1985); Braithwaite and Fisse, "Varieties of Responsibilities and Organizational Crime," Law and Policy 7: 315-343 (1985); Vaughan, Controlling Unlawful Organizational Behavior (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983); Fisse and Braithwaite, The Impact of Publicity on Corporate Offenders (SUNY Press, 1983); Shapiro, Wayward Capitalists (Yale University Press, 1984); Hawkins and Thomas (eds.), Enforcing Regulation (Kluwer-Nijhoff, 1984).
[65] This observation should help put to rest some of the sterile, but no less contentious, academic debate of who set the agenda and otherwise control the work of the academically free - professionally insulated and individually independent minded - scholars. The academic researchers, much like the Supreme Court Justices, have different roles to play. As professionals they remain aloof from the crowd. As citizens, they are responsive and responsible to listen to the drum of the populace. In the end, their work will reflect the values and concerns of the time - albeit ever so discreetly and surreptitious. This, in the jargon of the academic arena, is called being relevant.
[66] For a superb journalistic account of the era, see Godfrey Hodgson, American in Our Time (Vintage Books, 1976).
[67] See Mark Dowie, "Pinto Madness," Mother Jones September-October, 1977, pp. 18-32; See also CBS News. "Is Your Car Safe?" 60 minutes, Vol. 10, no. 40. Broadcast of the CBS television network, Sunday, 11 June 1978.
[68] See Robert Sherill, "The Case Against the Oil Companies," October 14, 1979, New York Times Magazine.
[69] See Michael H. Brown, "Love Canal and the Poising of America," in Mark Green and Robert Massie, Jr. (eds.), The Big Business Reader (N.Y.: Pilgrim Press, 1980),
[70] See Report of the Commission to Investigate Allegations of Police Corruption and the City's Anti-Corruption Procedures (Knapp Commission), 1972.
[71] See Nelson, Cointelpro: The FBI Secret War on Political Freedom (N.Y.: Random House, 1976), FBI Jackson, "FBI Admits It Opened Mail in Eight Cities in Illegal Program Parallel to that of CIA," L.A. Times, October 2, 1975.
[72] See Carl Bernstein and Bob Woodward, All The President's Men (New York: Warner Publishing, 1974.
[73] David Garland observed in Punishment and Modern Society (Chicago University Press, 1990) that "sources of penal change and the determinants of penal form are located not just in penological reasoning or economic interest, or strategic of power, but in the configurations of value, meaning, and emotion which we call 'culture."
[74] See Ralph Nader, Unsafe at Any Speed (New York, Grossman: 1965). The book that start of the consumer movement against big business.
[75] See Mark Green, Ralph Nader and Joel Seligman, Taming the Giant Corporation (1976).
[76] Marshall B. Clinard and Peter C. Yeager, "Corporate Crime: Issues in Research," Criminology 16:255-272 (1978).
[77] The renewed in interest in white-collar crime in 1970-80, particular those perpetrated by big, impersonal organizations, is thus not accidental.
[78] See e.g. Conference on White-collar Crime in 1974 by Simon Dinitz, Herbert Edelhertz and John Conrad. See Diane C. Vaughan, Crime Between Organization (Ph.D. dissertation, Ohio State University, 1979), Chapter II, note 47, p. 71. Conference on White-collar and Economic Crime: Trends and Problems in Research and Policy: Multidisciplinary and Cross National Perspectives, held at SUNY College of Arts and Science, Postdam, New York, 7-9 February, 1980. Panels were organized at academic conferences. See M. David Ermann and Richard J. Lundman, "Deviant Acts by Complex Organizations: Deviant and Social Control at the Organizational Level of Analysis," paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Sociological Association, San Francisco, 1975; James Frey, "Some General Observations on Deviant Behavior by Organizations," paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Sociological Association, Chicago, 1977 and Laura Shill Schrager and James F. Short, Jr., "Toward a Definition of Organizational Crime," paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Sociological Association," Chicago, 1977.
[79] The increase funding to the academia was part of a larger state and national effort to fight white-collar crime. The National District Attorneys' Association joined force with the Academy for Contemporary Problems (Columbus, Ohio) to conduct research "which would both enhance prosecution capabilities in the area of economic crime and also give new impetus to criminological research into his area." Herbert Edelhertz, "National District Attorneys' Association Demonstration Project: Economic Crime," in Diane Vaughan (ed.). Monograph on Economic Crime (Columbus Ohio, 1974), Unpublished. LEAA funding was made available for law enforcement (special units for prosecution of white-collar crime in selected cities across the United States) and research projects (e.g. 5 year research program at Yale as "the beginning of a substantial and increasing commitment on the federal level to response to white-collar crime and corruption." See Bernard Auchter, "Federal Level Research and Demonstration in White-collar Crime Control: Efforts of the Law Enforcement Assistant Administration," paper presented at American Society of Criminology, Annual Meeting, Dallas Texas, November 8-12, 1978.
[80] See Diane C. Vaughan, Crime Between Organizations (PHD thesis: Ohio State University, 1979)., pp. 55-56.
[81] Herbert Edelhertz redefined white-collar crime as economic crime: "An illegal act or series of acts committed by concealment or guile, to obtain money or property, to avoid the payment or loss of money of property, or to obtain business or personal advantage." The Nature, Impact and Prosecution of White-collar Crime, National Institute of Law Enforcement and Criminal Justice, U.S. Department of Justice, Law Enforcement Assistance Administration, 1970, p. 3. Note this definition emphasize on the nature of the offense instead of the status of the offender. In so doing, it captures much of Sutherland's concern, i.e. people obtaining economic advantage by "concealment and guile" (usually by breach of trust) without being faithful to his original definition, that of "crime committed by a person of respectability and high social status."
[82] It is difficult to trace intellectual history. Literal citations, personal acknowledgment and biographic reconstruction provide some of the sources to track some of the ideas. Most of the time they are incomplete to grasp fully the inter-connectedness of a stock of ideas, through time and across discipline. Most ideas are inter-related directly in some way, either logically or temporally; making it easy to observe the connection. However, when concepts and ideas are indirectly related, when they are tangentially interconnected, when they are separated in space and time and when the an idea belong to stock of ideas which provides needed stimulation and necessary context for the development of other ideas (for each other, in parallel or later), much is left to speculation and conjecture. Abstract ideas do exhibit continuity and inter-dependency. For an enlightening discussion on evolution of ideas, see Merton, "On The History and Systematics of Sociological Theory," in Social Theory and Social Structure (New York: Free Press, 1968), pp. 1-39.
[83] It is of interest to note, whether it is in politics, law or academic world, the first step to debunk a traditional ideology, established precedent or dominant paradigm is not by challenging its legitimacy completely or disagreeing with it totally but to acknowledge its dominance and merits and seek only to modify it in part - textually, spiritually or directionally. Such a strategy allow the new ideas to gain legitimacy and foothold. To attempt a frontal attack on existing ideas is much like attempting revolution in the face of a repressive regime; it is suicidal.
[84] See Richard Quinney, "The Study of White-Collar Crime: Toward a Re-orientation in Theory and Research," in Gilbert Deis and Robert F. Meier, (eds.), White-Collar Crime (New York: Free Press, 1977), p. 285.
[85] See Marshall B. Clinard, The Black Market (New York: Rinehart and Co,. Inc. 1952), p. 127.
[86] Newman focused on violator's occupational role more so than his social status in classifying white-collar criminal. Donald J. Newman, "White-Collar Crime: An Overview and Analysis" Ibid. p. 52,
[87] Defining white-collar crime by social status is controversial: it is very nebulous to behold, impossible to articulate and too subjective and value laden to sustain any critical analysis.
[88] See Lawrence W. Sherman, Scandal and Reform (Berkeley: University of California press, 1978), p. 6.
[89] See Stone, Where the Law Ends (N.Y.: Harper and Row, 1980), p. 50 (examining the relationship between corporate organizational structure and informational flow); Clinard and Yeager (1980), supra, p. 131 (examining the relationship between market power and presence of violations among manufacturing corporations); Vaughan (1983) (examining the relationship between exernal environmental factors and internal corporate behavior)
[90] Neal Shover, "Defining Organizational Crime," in M. David Ermann and Richard J. Lundman (eds.), Corporate and Governmental Deviance: Problems of Organizational Behavior in Contemporary Society (New York: Oxford, 1978), pp. 28-36.
[91] These critical distinctions in the study of organizational crime are made explicit in Sherman's definitive study on control of deviant organization. See Scandal and Reform.
[92] See Ermann and Lundman, Organizational Deviance (1981), cited in Diane Vaughan, Crime Between Organizations (Ph.D. Thesis: Ohio State University, 1979), p. 61.
[93] See Lawrence Sherman, Scandal and Reform (Berkeley, University of California Press, 1978).
[94] See ibid. p. 6.
[95] See ibid. pp. 7-15.
[96] See ibid. p. 13.
[97] An examination of Sherman's work on deviant organizations, Chapter 1 "Deviant Organizations," in Scandal and Reform, op. cit.., showed that there is only one reference (out of 46 footnotes) to a major white-collar crime work, that of Sutherland's White-collar Crime (1949). It was cited as "first sociological discussion of deviant organizations." See ibid. footnote 1.