AustLII Home | Databases | WorldLII | Search | Feedback

University of Melbourne Law School Research Series

Melbourne Law School
You are here:  AustLII >> Databases >> University of Melbourne Law School Research Series >> 2008 >> [2008] UMelbLRS 4

Database Search | Name Search | Recent Articles | Noteup | LawCite | Author Info | Download | Help

Beaton-Wells, C --- "The Politics of Cartel Criminalisation: A Pessimistic View from Australia" [2008] UMelbLRS 4

Last Updated: 30 June 2009

The politics of cartel criminalisation: a pessimistic view from Australia

Caron Beaton-Wells[*]

Since the late 1990s there has been a global movement towards tougher enforcement of anti-cartel laws, including the proscription of criminal penalties for serious cartel conduct[1] or so-called “hard-core” collusion.[2] The movement has been orchestrated by the United States’ antitrust authorities as part of an aggressive strategy to deal with international cartels.[3] A decade on and there are now a substantial number of countries across every continent that have introduced criminal sanctions for collusion between competitors.[4] However, in many instances, the challenges involved in implementing and enforcing a criminal regime in jurisdictions outside of the United States are also only just becoming evident.[5]

In particular, questions are being asked about the extent to which criminalisation has the support of key stakeholders, whose support is critical to ensuring that the deterrent threat of criminal penalties is real and not simply theoretical.[6] In Japan, for example, criticism has been directed in the past at the regulator, the Japanese Fair Trade Commission, in relation to perceived reticence on its part to bring criminal actions for breaches of its competition laws.[7] In Ireland, recent experience with price fixing prosecutions has led to concerns about the level of commitment on the part of the prosecutorial and judicial authorities to criminal enforcement.[8] In Britain, recent empirical research casts doubt on whether members of the public, from which jurors will be drawn for cartel trials, will embrace the idea of sending price fixers to jail.[9]

However, perhaps even more disturbingly, the Australian experience to date highlights the difficulty of shifting to a criminal regime without sufficient political support. That experience, charted in this article, demonstrates that without a strong commitment by the national government, cartel criminalisation may be doomed from the start. In Australia, the campaign to criminalise was initiated and has been led by the regulator, the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (“ACCC”). Yet, despite a high profile, politically astute and seemingly effective campaign by the ACCC, questions remain as to when criminalising legislation is likely to be introduced and, when (or if) enacted, whether it will have the level of practical support by government required for its proper enforcement. Australia is not alone in facing such questions. Sweden, for example, is another country in which the government entertains serious reservations about criminalisation as an appropriate response to cartels, albeit in that jurisdiction, unlike in Australia, it appears that such reservations are shared by the regulator.[10] In Austria, in 2002 criminal sanctions in fact were removed from the statute books for all breaches of the cartel prohibitions (except bid rigging). This was at the behest of a newly elected conservative government that apparently saw decriminalisation as an important element of its promised “modernization” of business law.[11]

After summarising the background, this article sets out the aspects of the Australian government’s approach to cartel criminalisation to date that give cause for concern and, where relevant, draws comparisons with the experience in Britain. In particular, it draws attention to:

Background

In 2001 the then Chairman of the ACCC, Allan Fels, called for the introduction of criminal sanctions for serious forms of business collusion in Australia.[12] The call for criminalisation was formalised in the ACCC’s submission[13] to an independent committee (“the Dawson Committee”) charged with the task of reviewing Australia’s competition legislation, the Trade Practices Act 1974 (Cth) (“the Act”), in 2002.[14] In its January 2003 report, the Committee agreed that the current civil penalty regime was an insufficient deterrent to the business community and it recommended that criminal sanctions be introduced, subject to the resolution of definitional and procedural issues and consideration of the implications for the ACCC’s leniency policy.[15]

The government accepted the recommendation of the Dawson Committee “in principle” and promised to “further consider” the matter, while guardedly emphasising the need for any new criminal penalty regime to apply broadly, not to impose “significant additional uncertainty and complexity for business” and to “work well in the context of the Australian legal system.”[16] A government working party on penalties for cartel behaviour was convened in October 2003 for the purposes of resolving these and other issues.[17] The working party reported to the government some time in 2004 and on 2 February 2005, the Treasurer announced in a press release that criminal sanctions for “serious cartel behaviour” would be introduced.[18] The “cartel offence” proposed by the Treasurer would:

“Prohibit a person from making or giving effect to a contract, arrangement or understanding between competitors that contains a provision to fix prices, restrict output, divide markets or rig bids, where the contract, arrangement or understanding is made or given effect to with the intention of dishonestly obtaining a gain from the customers who fall victim to the cartel.”[19]

The proposal indicated that the maximum penalties for individuals for a cartel offence will be a term of imprisonment of five years and a fine of AU $220,000.[20] For corporations, reflecting civil provisions introduced with effect from 1 January 2007, a fine that is the greatest of AU $10 million or three times the value of the benefit derived from the cartel or where that value cannot be ascertained, 10% of annual group turnover.[21]

Historical reluctance

A historical account of the approach taken to trade practices penalties indicates a strong reluctance on the part of Australian governments, particularly of a Liberal (conservative) persuasion, to embrace a criminal mode of enforcement.[22] In the first attempt at competition regulation in this country, the Australian Industries Preservation Act 1906 (Cth), there were criminal penalties that attached to the prohibitions on restraints of trade and monopolisation,[23] reflecting developments in the United States and the provisions of the Sherman Act 1890. However, in what may now appear as something of a legislative aberration, those penalties have been explained on the basis that the legislation was aimed largely at curtailing incursions by overseas business interests into Australian markets.[24] They thus did not require the government to confront the notion of treating Australian businessmen as criminals. The legislation had a short life in any event, being declared largely constitutionally invalid by the High Court in litigation concerning the reserved powers of the Commonwealth in 1909.[25]

Criminal penalties were removed from the subsequent Trade Practices Act 1965 (Cth) which, being modelled predominantly on the English rather than the American approach to antitrust, adopted an administrative rather than a judicial method of enforcement.[26] One explanation for this backward step in enforcement terms may be that, in this instance “the businessmen affected were Australian, and very much ‘like us’ as far as the Government was concerned. Such men could not be criminal and it was inappropriate to criminalise their business behaviour.”[27] Amendments in 1971, again at the instigation of a Liberal government, declaring resale price maintenance illegal, were similarly non-criminal in character, allowing for civil damages and injunctive orders to be made.[28]

The current Act was introduced by a Labor government the members of which, it has been said, were “far less inclined than the Liberals to imagine themselves in the position of businessmen.”[29] Their “basic impulse” to criminalise found expression in the case of the consumer protection provisions but stopped short of full criminalisation in the case of the competition provisions, opting instead for the hybrid pecuniary penalty on account, it seems, of concerns that criminal penalties would be more difficult to enforce.[30] The difference in approach taken to the two sets of provisions might also be explained by the fact that many of the practices covered by the consumer protection provisions (misleading advertising, false pretences and the like) involved an element of fraud, long recognised as a criminal offence. On the other hand there was little precedent in English law for classifying the practices covered by the restrictive trade provisions as criminal offences.[31]

In 1977, unhappy about the criminal sanctions in the Act but sensitive to the increasingly powerful consumer lobby, the then Liberal-Country Party coalition government retained criminal offences for contraventions of the consumer protection prohibitions, but removed the option of imprisonment.[32] Since then, the possibility of re-introducing criminal penalties for breach of the competition provisions has been toyed with at times but not seriously considered,[33] that is, until the ACCC’s proposal in 2001. With the benefit of this historical perspective, the significance of the current proposal from the government’s point of view starts to become apparent and its reticence to act at least understandable (even if not defensible).

Delay

It has been more than four and a half years since the recommendation by the Dawson Committee that serious cartel conduct be criminalised and the government is yet to introduce the relevant legislation to Parliament. The Treasury papers for the 2006 Commonwealth Budget indicated that the legislation would be introduced to Parliament in the winter sittings of that year.[34] However, the bill was not introduced. No explanation for the delay was offered. However, it was evident that the government in effect was pipelining the various trade practices reform packages then under consideration, using the promised cartel crime bill as leverage in negotiation with parliamentarians who were standing in the way of its other reforms, relating primarily to merger review processes and predatory pricing provisions.

In August 2007, the Trade Practices Amendment (Cartel Conduct and Other Measures) Bill and Federal Court Amendment (Criminal Jurisdiction) Bill were listed on the government’s website as legislation proposed to be introduced in the spring sittings of Parliament.[35] Almost certainly non-coincidentally, this listing occurred within days of increased pressure to take action over petrol prices (and renewed ACCC calls for criminal sanctions for cartel conduct in this context),[36] as well as publicity given to significant penalties for price fixing in the air-conditioning industry,[37] a global airline cargo cartel in which the national carrier Qantas has been implicated[38] and the announcement of an ACCC investigation into price fixing in stevedoring operations on Australian wharves.[39] Subsequently, a federal election intervened and the fate of bills was left hanging on the outcome.

Even with acknowledgment of the historical significance of the reform and the complexities involved in drafting the relevant provisions, such delay may still be described as “without defence.”[40] This is particularly so when one compares the process recently undertaken in Britain. There the government issued a White Paper proposing criminal sanctions for cartel conduct in July 2001 and the Enterprise Act 2002 (UK) containing the criminal provisions was introduced to Parliament, less than a year subsequently, in March 2002. It received Royal Assent on 7 November 2002.

Clearly, there are differences between the Australian and British experience with competition regulation which may explain why the process was so much quicker and evidently much less agonising in the latter jurisdiction than in the former. In Britain it was no doubt material that cartel criminalisation was just one element of an overall shake-up of competition policy by the British Labor government following its re-election - a shake-up likely to have been influenced to a large extent by the increasingly active approach to enforcement on the part of the European Commission.[41] Thus, in Britain, criminalisation was an initiative that was driven by the government rather than by the Office of Fair Trading (“OFT”) which, up until the reforms in 1998, had been a relatively weak and ineffectual authority.[42] Whereas, in Australia, by contrast the criminalisation initiative was led by the ACCC rather than the government and in a climate in which the government had been under siege by the big business lobby for some years to rein in a regulator that was viewed as too powerful and increasingly unaccountable.[43]

Moreover, events in the course of the current Australian election campaign have given further reason to doubt the government’s commitment to cartel criminalisation. In October 2007, the ACCC scored a major victory in an action it had taken in relation to cartel conduct in the cardboard packaging industry by one of Australia’s largest manufacturing companies, the Visy group, and their owner, billionaire and reknown philanthropist, Richard Pratt. Agreement was reached to settle the case involving admissions, a public apology and submission to record-level penalties, more than doubling the previous maximum corporate penalty imposed for collusion in Australia.[44] It might have been expected that these events, which received extensive media coverage, would provide the government with the welcome opportunity to justify and explain further its commitment to criminal penalties for such conduct. However, to the contrary, in the inevitable media frenzy that followed, several political leaders (not least of all, the Prime Minister) expressed publicly their admiration for Pratt and his contribution to Australian business and society.[45]

Indeed, in the same breath as praising and indicating his personal liking of the Visy owner, the Prime Minister refused to commit the government to cartel criminalisation.[46] This led to a conflicting statement by the Treasurer[47] and subsequent media reports suggested that in fact there was also a degree of backbencher unrest about the proposal given its implications for small business owners.[48] There were also reports that, despite supporting criminalisation in its submission to the Dawson Committee, there are some members of the powerful business lobby group (the Business Council of Australia), who have been pressuring the government to abandon its proposal.[49] All in all, the resultant impression is of a government under siege and struggling with substantial internal conflict and uncertainty about whether criminalisation is a step that is both necessary and desirable.

Deficient process

Given the significance of this change in approach to cartel regulation in Australia, it might have been expected that the government would engage in a transparent and consultative process to ensure not only that the reform is justified but also that the complexities involved in its design and implementation would be resolved with input from all relevant stakeholders. The process to date, however, has been just the opposite.

The Dawson Committee, which did have the benefit of submissions from a range of bodies and persons on the subject, failed inexplicably to tackle the issues in depth, hand-balling it back to the government with only an “in principle” recommendation.[50] The working party comprising representatives from the ACCC, the Attorney-General’s Department and the Commonwealth Director of Public Prosecutions, was then convened. The working party did not call for submissions publicly, it is not known whether it undertook any consultation beyond the bodies represented upon it and it did not release its report or its recommendations for public consumption. A subsequent request for access to its report under freedom of information (“FOI”) legislation was refused by Treasury and it was indicated that consideration was being given to issuing a conclusive certificate to deny access to the report on public interest grounds.[51] The effect of such a certificate would be to limit substantially the type of merits review available in respect of a refusal of access under the FOI statute. However, on even this question, the government is delaying in making a decision – delay that it is hard to conclude is not politically motivated given the election campaign and the media coverage being given to the issue in light of the Visy affair.[52]

The process adopted in relation to the working party is inconsistent with the government’s Office of Best Practice Regulation policy statement.[53] It is in marked contrast to the practice commonly adopted in the areas of corporate and financial services regulation in which public discussion papers or draft exposure bills are routinely released in relation to proposed amendments. Indeed, somewhat ironically, the government is currently undertaking a review of sanctions for contraventions of corporate law (even more ironically, one of the questions being whether to scale back reliance on criminal sanctions) and that review is being undertaken in the public arena with extensive provision for consultation.[54] What arguably should have occurred in relation to cartel criminalisation is that the government should have referred it to the Australian Law Reform Commission which has a strong track record of dealing with difficult and complex subjects, and publishing detailed reports with clear recommendations based on wide consultation. Moreover, this body only recently examined and reported on the related subjects of federal civil and administrative penalties and sentencing of federal offenders and hence would be well placed to examine the issues involved in cartel criminalisation.[55]

The Australian process may also be compared with the process in Britain where the government published its White Paper in which it set out its intention to criminalise hard-core cartels, its rationale for this approach and the basic elements of the proposed criminal regime.[56] The White Paper called for comments and submissions to inform the legislative drafting process.[57] This was followed by the publication of a report commissioned by the OFT by Sir Anthony Hammond QC and Sir Roy Penrose OBE on the legislative and procedural changes required to operate a criminal regime.[58] The report indicates that the authors interviewed 51 people associated with the initiative.[59] Upon publishing it on its website, the OFT invited comments on any aspect of the report.[60]

Problematic aspects of offence design and enforcement policy

There are aspects of the government’s proposed design and policy for enforcement of the cartel offence that are ill-conceived and appear not to have been properly thought through. Two, in particular, may be singled out for criticism.[61]

First, it is proposed that dishonesty be an element of the mens rea for the offence.[62] This proposal mirrors the approach that has been taken in the United Kingdom,[63] albeit in no other jurisdiction that has a criminal regime.[64] In both jurisdictions, the rationale for introducing this requirement has been that it will facilitate distinction between the conduct attracting criminal penalties and conduct that will remain subject to the civil prohibition.[65] In short, dishonesty has been seen as a way of communicating the seriousness of the conduct that is subject to criminal sanctions.[66] Yet this, as a rationale, has been described as “seriously flawed.”[67] The common law test of dishonesty, invoking the “standards of ordinary people” and the idea that defendant have known his or her conduct to be dishonest according to such standards,[68] has been shown in other contexts to cause problems for juries.[69] It will almost undoubtedly be problematic also in relation to cartel activity given the ambiguity surrounding both the harmfulness[70] and moral wrongfulness[71] of such activity.

Apparently, in supporting the requirement of dishonesty despite these evident flaws, the Australian government has chosen to ignore even the advice of the Commonwealth Director of Public Prosecutions – quite astonishingly, given that it is the DPP (or members of that office) who will be responsible for persuading juries of guilt under the new offence.[72] Indeed, the DPP’s concerns appear borne out by the recent British research, referred to earlier, which confirms that juries are likely to struggle with these concepts. A March 2007 survey of the British public found that only 6 in 10 Britons (63% of respondents) regard price fixing as dishonest, many (65%) could not relate price fixing to any other practice with which they were familiar (only 7% thought theft, 8% fraud) and, perhaps most disconcertingly, only 1 in 10 (11%) considered that it warranted imprisonment.[73]

Secondly, in an attempt to confine the proposed criminal regime in Australia to cartel conduct that is “serious” in terms of harm to competition, it has been proposed that the ACCC criminally investigate only those cases in which the combined value of the line of commerce affected by the cartel exceeds AU $1 million within a twelve month period.[74] This aspect of the proposal bears some resemblance to the approach taken in the United Kingdom where one of the questions asked by the Serious Fraud Office in deciding whether or not to prosecute under the cartel offence in that jurisdiction is whether “the value of the alleged fraud exceed[s] £1 million.”[75] However, the importance of this criterion is downplayed somewhat, described as “simply an objective and recognisable signpost of seriousness and likely public concern rather than a main indicator of suitability.” [76]

As has been pointed out elsewhere, that the fact the value of commerce affected by the cartel conduct exceeds AU $1 million does not in itself mean that the impact on competition has been serious.[77] Thus, the threshold, being based on a fixed monetary value, has the potential to be both under-inclusive and over-inclusive, depending on the size of the market in which the cartel members operate.[78] One possible solution that has been suggested is that prosecutions be limited to cases where the specific line of commerce likely to be affected by the cartel represents a minimum percentage (say, based on the US Sentencing Guidelines, 20%) of the value of sales by all competitors who compete in that specific line of commerce in the relevant geographic market over a relevant time period, linked to the commission of the offence.[79] However, that rather sensible suggestion has been rejected by the government.[80] Questions also have been raised as to whether the threshold should be made a jurisdictional element of the offence, or whether it should be merely a guide to the exercise of prosecutorial discretion.[81]

Underwhelming sanctions

In relation to the proposed sanctions, a maximum term of imprisonment of five years is by no means an overwhelming indicator of the government’s supposed conviction regarding the need for criminal sanctions for serious cartel conduct. A recurring rationale offered for cartel criminalisation by both the regulator and politicians is that it is analogous to other so-called “white collar” criminal offences and hence should be treated analogously.[82] However, even a cursory glance at the Commonwealth Criminal Code Act 1995 (Cth) demonstrates that what is proposed by the government does not amount to analogous treatment. Under the Code, the offences of obtaining property by deception and conspiracy to defraud a Commonwealth entity attract a maximum jail term of 10 years.[83] Such comparisons have led one commentator aptly to remark that the proposed maximum is “difficult to reconcile with the rhetoric of politicians and others that serious cartel conduct is akin to theft, fraud or extortion.”[84]

In terms of international standards the proposed maximum jail term could also be said to smack of compromise. It is certainly nowhere near the top end of the scale, alongside countries such as the United States and Mexico that have a 10 year maximum. Rather, it could be described as “middle-of-the-range”,[85] bearing in mind that there are other jurisdictions including Britain, at the same level as is proposed in Australia with five years;[86] and others below that, with maximum terms of 3 or 4 years.[87]

It is proposed further that individuals be subject to a maximum fine of AU $220,000.[88] However, the current civil maximum is AU $500,000. This disparity is mystifying, especially when the position in other jurisdictions is compared – in the United States the maximum individual penalty is US $1 million[89] and in the United Kingdom, it is unlimited.[90] One explanation for the low maximum is that criminal conviction also attracts other adverse consequences including the social stigma of being branded a criminal and being excluded or disqualified from certain activities.[91] However, such reasoning “does not explain why, in cases where jail is not considered by a court to be an appropriate sentence, the maximum fine should be lower than the maximum civil penalty for the same or very similar conduct.”[92] A possible explanation is that the proposed maximum fine would be commensurate with the position under the Corporations Act 2001 (Cth) which provides for fines of up to AU $220,000 for individuals who breach its criminal provisions.

Inadequate powers and resources

The evidentiary challenges involved in proving a cartel conspiracy have been apparent under even a civil regime for some time and have been highlighted in recent litigation brought by the ACCC in relation to price fixing in the petrol industry.[93] Criminalisation will only aggravate these difficulties given the higher standard of proof. With this in mind, the government’s willingness to authorise telecommunications interception and other modes of electronic surveillance for the purposes of criminal investigations will be critical. So far, it is unclear whether the government will be prepared to invest the ACCC with this kind of power.

With the proposed maximum jail term of 5 years, it will not be possible to obtain a warrant for telecommunications interception under the Telecommunications (Interception and Access) Act 1979 (Cth), given that that Act applies only in relation to offences with a 7 year jail term.[94] Media reports suggest that the ACCC will be required to refer requests for phone–tapping to the Australian Federal Police.[95] This may cause delay and give rise to inter-agency bungling. It may even lead the ACCC to consider proceeding under other offences, such as conspiracy to defraud,[96] which do allow for telecommunication interceptions.[97] Antitrust authorities in the United States, Canada and the United Kingdom have such powers.[98] Moreover, other Australian corporate regulators have them.[99] It is difficult to understand why the ACCC should be any different.

In terms of financial support, a funding package for the agencies involved in implementing the new criminal regime in Australia was announced in May 2006.[100] The package included AU $18.2 million over four years for legal expenses for the ACCC and AU $7.2 million to support investigations and enforcement. It further included AU $4.4 million over four years for the DPP for cartel prosecutions and AU $3.9 million for the Federal Court to hear cartel trials. Leading practitioners have described these figures as inadequate to fund major cartel prosecutions against the powerful, often internationally supported, deep-pocketed interests behind serious cartel activity.[101] In the Visy case, for example, the respondents agreed to pay the ACCC’s costs estimated at between AU $10 million and AU $20 million,[102] that is conceivably equal to the entire amount allocated to the ACCC over four years to meet all of its criminal cartel-related expenses. Of course, these figures pale into insignificance when compared with the fees generated in the United States and Europe where cartel litigation has become “significant legal business.”[103]

Implications

Political support for cartel criminalisation is essential for several reasons. First, and most obviously, such support is necessary in order for the necessary legislation to be drafted, introduced to Parliament and, ultimately, enacted. Secondly, the government will need to be prepared to consult widely and work through the complex and, at times, controversial aspects of the legislation – in particular, as it relates to the scope of the new offence and the sanctions imposed for its commission. Thirdly, it is inevitable that the government’s commitment to criminalisation will be tested by lobbying on the part of business groups and their political sympathisers seeking to prevent the legislation being introduced and/or to curtail the extent of the powers and resources given to the agencies charged with implementing it.[104] Fourthly, the government must be prepared to invest those agencies with adequate powers and resources to vigorously enforce the criminal regime, taking on formidable opponents and their legal teams. Finally, the extent to which the attitude of the government towards criminalisation will shape the perceptions of other stakeholders should not be underestimated. Business, the public, the media and, to a lesser extent the judiciary, will take cues from their political leaders as to the desirability and appropriateness of criminal penalties for cartel participants.

On each of these points, the Australian government scores poorly in its performance to date. There is still good reason to think that criminalising legislation will be enacted in this country, and that it is a question of when rather than if Australia will join the United States’ “coalition of the willing” in introducing criminal penalties for serious cartel conduct. This is especially so if the opposition Labor party takes government on 24 November 2007 (as the polls suggest is likely) given that it has indicated its intention to introduce criminal sanctions within 12 months, if elected.[105] That said, for the reasons previously cited, continuing political support will be necessary if the new regime is to be effectively enforced.

The difficulties being experienced outside of the United States in garnering support for cartel criminalisation from relevant stakeholders have been described as “growing pains through which most of the developed world will establish effective criminal antitrust regimes.”[106] That is, indeed, an optimistic view. As the experience in Australia (and other places) attests, when manifested in a substantial lack of political will, such pains may prove fatal to a national criminalisation movement and can only weaken the progress being made at the international level to combat serious cartel activity wherever it occurs.



[*] Director of Studies, Competition Law, Melbourne Law School, University of Melbourne.

[1] See C. Harding, ‘Business Collusion as a Criminological Phenomenon: Exploring the Global Criminalisation of Cartels’ (2006) 14 Critical Criminology 181; D. E. Vann, and E. Litwin, ‘Recent Developments in international cartel enforcement’ in Global Competition Review, Cartel Regulation: Getting the fine down in 37 jurisdictions worldwide (2007).

[2] “Hard-core” was the term adopted by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development to identify those practices that it considered “the most egregious violations of competition law” in its Recommendation of the Council Concerning Effective Action Against Hard Core Cartels (1998). It is a term that since has achieved widespread usage.

[3] Harding, above n 1, 194-197. The role of the United States in this regard is acknowledged in its own literature. See eg S. Hammond, ‘Charting New Waters in International Cartel Prosecutions’, Paper presented at the 20th Annual National Institute on White Collar Crime, 2 March 2006; T. Barnett, ‘Global Antitrust Enforcement’, paper presented at Georgetown Law Global Antitrust Enforcement Symposium, 26 September 2007, viewed at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/speech_2007.htm [Accessed 19 October 2007].

[4] As at 2006, the list of countries providing criminal liability for cartel participation included Austria, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Croatia, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Korea, Japan, Mexico, Norway, Slovak Republic, South Korea, Switzerland, the United Kingdom and the United States. Many of these did not have criminal cartel laws prior to the mid-1990s.

[5] Harding, above n 1, 192-194; A. Riley, ‘Editorial – Developing Criminal Cartel Law: Dealing with the Growing Pains’ (2007) 4(1) Competition Law Review 1.

[6] Such questions in turn suggest the need for consideration of more fundamental issues such as whether the criminalisation movement is a movement of conversion, convergence or globalisation of antitrust enforcement. Those issues, not tackled in this brief article, are examined in C. Harding and J. Joshua, Regulating Cartels in Europe: A Study of Legal Control in Corporate Delinquency (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2003), Chp X.

[7] K. Sanekata and S. Wilks, ‘The Fair Trade Commission and the enforcement of competition policy in Japan’ in G. B. Doern and S. Wilks (ed), Comparative Competition Policy: National Institutions in a Global Market (1996) (Oxford: Oxford University Press). Admittedly, since this criticism was made, the JFTC has had some significant cartel prosecution successes and has recently had its powers strengthened: see Hammond, above n 3.

[8] P. Andrews, ‘Modernisation – Irish Style’ (2002) ECLR 23; M. E. Curtis and J. McNally, ‘The Classic Cartel Hatch-Back Sentence’ (2007) 4(1) Competition Law Review 41.

[9] A. Stephan, ‘Survey of Public Attitudes to Price-Fixing and Cartel Enforcement in Britain’, CCP Working Paper 07-12, Economic & Social Research Council, Centre for Competition Policy and Norwich Law School, University of East Anglia, 3, http://www.ccp.uea.ac.uk/publicfiles/workingpapers/CCP07-12.pdf [Accessed 24 July 2007].

[10] C. Norgren, Director-General, Swedish Competition Authority, ‘Criminal Enforcement of Antitrust Laws’, Fordham Law Seminar, New York, 14 September 2006 at http://www.kkv.se/upload/Filer/Press/Tal-artiklar/tal_cn_060907.pdf [Accessed 1 November 2007].

[11] P. Lewisch, ‘Enforcement of antitrust law: the way from criminal individual punishment to semi-penal sanctions in Austria’ in K. Cseres, M. P. Schinkel and F. Vogelaar, Criminalization of Competition Law Enforcement (Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA, USA, 2006), 290, 291-295. A similar “u-turn” was made in the Netherlands in 1998: see P. Kalbfleisch, ‘Criminal competition law sanctions in the Netherlands’ in K. Cseres, M. P. Schinkel and F. Vogelaar, Criminalization of Competition Law Enforcement (Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA, USA, 2006), 312, 313.

[12] A. Fels, ‘Regulating in a High-Tech Marketplace’ (Paper presented at the Australian Law Reform Commission Conference on Penalties: Policy, principles and practice in government regulation, Sydney, 9 June 2001), http://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/255481 [Accessed 27 April 2007].

[13] Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, ACCC: Submission to the Trade Practices Act Review (2002), http://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/303044 [Accessed 27 April 2007].

  1. [14] Trade Practices Committee of Review, Review of the Competition Provisions of the Trade Practices Act, January 2003, http://tpareview.treasury.gov.au [Accessed 25 October 2007].

[15] Ibid, 161-162.

[16] Commonwealth Government Response to the Review of the Competition Provisions of the Trade Practices Act 1974 http://www.treasurer.gov.au/tsr/content/publications/TPAResponse.asp [Accessed 17 August 2007].

[17] Treasurer, ‘Working Party to Examine Criminal Sanctions for Cartel Behaviour’, Press Release, 3 October 2003 http://www.treasurer.gov.au/tsr/content/pressreleases/2003/086.asp [Accessed 17 August 2007].

[18] Treasurer, ‘Criminal Penalties for Serious Cartel Behaviour’ (Press Release 2 February 2005, No. 4 of 2005) www.treasurer.gov.au/tsr/content/pressreleases/2005/004.asp [Accessed 20 April 2007]. (“Treasurer’s press release”).

[19] Ibid.

[20] Ibid.

[21] See Trade Practices Legislation Amendment Bill (No. 1) 2006 (Cth). These amendments were also consequent upon recommendations made by the Dawson Committee (see n 14 above).

[22] A. Hopkins, Crime, Law & Business: The Sociological Sources of Australian Monopoly Law, (Australian Institute of Criminology, 1978), 116-120.

[23] A first offence was punishable by a fine of up to five hundred pounds and a second offence by up to a year’s imprisonment: ibid, 116.

[24] Ibid, 118.

[25] Huddart Parker and Co Ltd v Moorehead [1909] HCA 36; (1909) 8 CLR 330.

[26] Hopkins, above n 22, 116-117. The Act created a procedure for the examination of questionable practices that could then be the subject of an order by the Trade Practices Tribunal, declaring them illegal. Contravention of such an order would lead to prosecution for contempt of the Tribunal (rather than for the practice itself).

[27] Ibid, 118.

[28] Ibid, 117.

[29] Ibid, 118-119.

[30] Ibid, 119.

[31] Ibid, 89.

[32] Ibid, 119-120.

[33] See the brief reference to criminalisation of contraventions of the competition provisions in Law Reform Commission, Compliance with the Trade Practices Act 1974, Report No. 68 (1992), [9.27].

[34] See Budget Paper No. 2 Part 2 – Expense Measures – Treasury (2006) http://www.budget.gov.au/2006-07/bp2/html/index.htm [Accessed 14 September 2007].

[35] Department of Prime Minister and Cabinet http://dpmc.gov.au/parliamentary/docs/proposed_legislation.doc [Accessed 17 August 2007].

[36] Editorial, ‘ACCC urges govt to introduce jail for petrol price fixing’, AAP General News, 11 June 2007; Editorial, ‘ACCC seeks bowser clout’, The Australian, 11 June 2007, 1, 2; M. Drummond, ‘Tougher cartel laws slated’, Australian Financial Review (Sydney), 3 August 2007, 28.

[37] M. Drummond, ‘$9.2m punishment for air-con cartel’, Australian Financial Review (Sydney), 27 July 2007, 18.

[38] S. Creedy, ‘Fines bolster class action against Qantas’ The Australian (Sydney), 6 August 2007.

[39] ‘ACCC institutes legal proceedings against stevedores and senior executives for alleged collusion’, Media release #233/07, 24 August 2007, http://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemID/796769/fromItemId/2332 [Accessed 30 August 2007].

[40] C. Hodgekiss, ‘Criminalising Cartels: A Slow Conversion? Comments’, commentary given at 5th annual UNISA Trade Practices Workshop, 19-20 October on paper by the author, ‘Criminalising Cartels: A Slow Conversion?’ (copies of paper and commentary are on file with the author).

[41] Harding and Joshua, above n 6, 260.

[42] D. Guy, ‘The UK’s experience with criminal law sanctions’ in K. Cseres, M. P. Schinkel and F. Vogelaar, Criminalization of Competition Law Enforcement (Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA, USA, 2006), 248, 248-249.

[43] See generally the account given of this power struggle between the regulator and big business in F. Brenchley, Allan Fels: A Portrait of Power (Australia: John Wiley & Sons Australia Ltd 2003); C. Parker, ‘The “Compliance Trap”: The Moral Message in Responsive Regulatory Enforcement’ (2006) 40(3) Law & Society Review 591; C. Parker and V. L. Nielsen, ‘What do Australian Businesses Really Think of the ACCC, and Does it Matter?’ (2007) FLR 1.

[44] See Australian Competition and Consumer Commission v Visy Industries Holdings Pty Limited (No 3) [2007] FCA 1617. A penalty of $36,000,000 was imposed on the corporate respondents (the previous maximum having been $15,000,000) and penalties of $1,500,000 and $500,000 on two individual respondents (the previous maximum having been $200,000).

[45] See ‘No plans to make price fixing criminal’, AAP, 9 October 2007; ‘PM back-pedals on cartel penalties’, Australian Financial Review, 10 October 2007, 1.

[46] Ibid.

[47] ‘Cartel behaviour should be criminal’, AAP, 9 October 2007.

[48] ‘Regulator to tap phones in cartels blitz’, Australian Financial Review, 24 October 2007, 1, 4.

[49] Ibid.

[50] See the criticisms of the Committee on this score in B. Fisse, ‘The Dawson Review: Enforcement and Penalties’ [2003] UNSWLawJl 23; (2003) 26(1) UNSWLJ 315, 317.

[51] B. Fisse, ‘The Cartel Offence: Dishonesty?’ (2007) 35 ABLR 235, 236, n 4. Documents relevant to the freedom of information request are available at http://www.brentfisse.com [Accessed 23 August 2007].

[52] B. Fisse, ‘Costello working hard to avoid action on cartels’, Australian Financial Review, 26 October 2007.

[53] See the Office’s policy statement on consultation at http://www.obpr.gov.au/consultation.html [Accessed 30 October 2007].

[54] See Review of Sanctions in Corporate Law paper at http://www.treasury.gov.au/contentitem.asp?Navid=037&ContentID=1182 [Accessed 13 September 2007].

[55] Australian Law Reform Commission, Principled Regulation: Federal Civil and Administrative Penalties in Australia, Report No. 95 (2002); Australian Law Reform Commission, Same Crime, Same Time: Sentencing of Federal Offenders, Report No. 103, 2006, http://www.alrc.gov.au [Accessed 4 August 2007].

[56] Department of Trade and Industry, ‘A World Class Competition Regime’, White Paper, CM 5233, 30 July 2001.

[57] Ibid.

[58] See Sir Anthony Hammond and R. Penrose, Proposed Criminalisation of Cartels in the UK, Report prepared for the Office of Fair Trading, United Kingdom (2001).

[59] Ibid, 42-44.

[60] Ibid, Foreword.

[61] Others are discussed in B. Fisse, ‘The Australian Cartel Criminalisation Proposals: An Overview and Critique’ (2007) 4(1) Competition Law Review 51. This article discusses not only those aspects of the proposals that have been made public but also several important elements of the new regime about which information is yet to be made available – for example, the approach to be taken to corporate responsibility under the cartel offence and the extent of powers of electronic surveillance to be given to the ACCC.

[62] Treasurer’s Press Release, above n 18.

[63] See Enterprise Act 2002 (UK), s 188.

[64] Note also that dishonesty is not mentioned in OECD, Fighting Hard-Core Cartels (2002) at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/41/44/1841891.pdf [Accessed 1 November 2007] or in ICN Working Group on Cartels, Defining Hard Core Cartel Conduct, Effective Institutions, Effective Penalties (2005) at http://www.internationalcompetitionnetwork.org/index.php/en/working-groups/cartels [Accessed 19 October 2007].

[65] Treasurer’s Press Release, above n 18l; Hammond and Penrose, above n 58.

[66] Hammond and Penrose, above n 58, 10 [2.5].

[67] Fisse, above n 61, 53.

[68] This test was articulated by the English Court of Appeal in R. v Ghosh (Deb Baran) [1982] EWCA Crim 2; [1982] Q.B. 1053 and has been codified in section 130.3 of the Criminal Code Act 1995 (Cth).

[69] As discussed in Fisse, above n 51, 255-257.

[70] In Australia, as elsewhere, such ambiguity is illustrated by the differential treatment given to cartel arrangements under the Act – some are treated as naked restraints and prohibited per se (the arrangements to be criminalized will be a subset of these), some are subject to the rule of reason, substantial lessening of competition standard. Then there are exemptions and defences (for example, for certain joint ventures) and added to that, a process of enabling arrangements to be authorised on public benefit grounds.

[71] See the discussion in C. Beaton-Wells, ‘Capturing the Criminality of Hard-Core Cartels: The Australian Proposal’ (2007) December MULR (forthcoming).

[72] ‘Regulator to tap phones in cartels blitz’, Australian Financial Review, 24 October 2007, 1, 4.

[73] Stephan, above n 9, 3.

[74] Treasurer’s Press Release, above n 18.

[75] Memorandum Of Understanding between the Office of Fair Trading and the Serious Fraud Office, October 2003, OFT 547, 5, http://www.oft.gov.uk [Accessed at 20 April 2007]. The other listed criteria are: “Is the case likely to give rise to national publicity and widespread public concern? Does the case require highly specialist knowledge of, for example, Stock Exchange procedures or regulated markets? Is there a significant international dimension? Will legal, accountancy and investigative skills need to be brought together? Is there a need to use the SFO’s special powers?”

[76] Ibid.

[77] J. Clarke, ‘Criminal Penalties for Contraventions of Part IV of the Trade Practices Act[2005] DeakinLawRw 8; (2005) 10 Deakin Law Review 141, 162.

[78] Fisse, above n 51, 246.

[79] Ibid.

[80] Letter from The Honourable Tony Smith MP, Parliamentary Secretary to the Prime Minister to Brent Fisse, 26 February 2007 (copy on file with author, kindly supplied by Brent Fisse).

[81] Fisse, above n 51, 246, 275; Beaton-Wells, above n 71.

[82] See most recently G. Samuel, ‘Cartel ringleaders are well-dressed criminals, so why not send them to jail?’, The Age, 3 November 2007, 19.

[83] For the offences of obtaining property by deception and conspiracy to defraud a Commonwealth entity, for example, the maximum jail term is 10 years (see Criminal Code Act 1995 (Cth), ss 13.1, 14.1)

[84] Fisse, above n 61, 66.

[85] Clarke, above n 77, 165.

[86] For example, the United Kingdom, Ireland, Canada and Israel all have five years: ibid.

[87] For example, France (4 years) and Japan (3 years): ibid.

[88] Treasurer’s Press Release, above n 18.

[89] Antitrust Criminal Penalty Enhancement and Reform Act 118 Stat 661 (2004).

[90] Enterprise Act 2002 (UK), s 190.

[91] Clarke, above n 77, 165.

[92] Fisse, above n 61, 66-67.

[93] See Australian Competition & Consumer Commission v Leahy Petroleum Pty Ltd [2007] FCA 794; (2007) 160 FCR 321, discussed in W. Pengilley, ‘ACCC fails in Geelong petrol price-fixing litigation: what are the lessons?’ (2007) 23(4) Australian & New Zealand Trade Practices Law Bulletin 54; K. Watts and J. Mortensen, ‘Recent Developments in cartel investigations and prosecutions’ (2007) 23(4) Australian & New Zealand Trade Practices Law Bulletin 61.

[94] Such a warrant is available only for offences carrying a 7 year maximum jail term: Telecommunications (Interception and Access) Act 1979 (Cth), s 5D. However, as Fisse points out, presumably a warrant for a surveillance device (other than telecommunications interception) would be available under s 14 of the Surveillance Devices Act 2004 (Cth): see Fisse, above n 61, 67.

[95] ‘Regulator to tap phones in cartels blitz’, Australian Financial Review, 24 October 2007, 1, 4.

[96] There are substantial similarities between the proposed cartel offence and the offence of conspiracy to defraud a Commonwealth entity under the Criminal Code (Cth), s 135.4. Notably, the Serious Fraud Office in the United Kingdom recently launched a major prosecution of a price fixing cartel for conspiracy to defraud (the cartel offence not having been enacted at the time that the relevant conduct took place), leading to some debate as to whether a wholly new offence is required to deal with such arrangements: see M. Furse and S. Nash, ‘A rose by any other name’ (2006) 156 New Law Journal 780; Cf the discussion in J. Lever and J. Pike ‘Cartel Agreements, Criminal Conspiracy and the Statutory “Cartel Offence” – Part I’ (2005) 26(2) European Competition Law Review 90; J. Lever and J. Pike, ‘Cartel Agreements, Criminal Conspiracy and the Statutory “Cartel Offence” – Part 2’ (2005) 26(3) European Competition Law Review 164, in which the differences between the common law conspiracy to defraud offence and the statutory cartel offence are identified. Of relevance to this debate also is the decision in Norris v The United States [2005] U.K.C.L.R. 1205; [2007] EWHC 71 in which it was held that Norris could be extradited to face cartel charges in the USA given that there was an equivalent offence at the same in the UK, namely the common law conspiracy to defraud offence.

[97] Fisse, above n 61, 67.

[98] See M. Racanelli, ‘Bugs in the Boardroom?’ (2006) (January) Antitrust Source 1; M. Furse and S. Nash, The Cartel Offence (Hart Publishing, 2004), 57-60 (and see further in relation to the powers of the Office of Fair Trading in the United Kingdom: OFT Code of Practice, August 2004, Covert Surveillance in Cartel Investigations; http://www.oft.gov.uk/advice_and_resources/publications/guidance/general/oft739 [Accessed 14 September 2007].

[99] Hodgekiss, above n 40, 12.

[100] The funding for the criminalisation proposal was described as “ongoing”. See http://treasurer.gov.au/tsr/content/pressreleases/2006/033.asp?pf+1 [Accessed 20 August 2007].

[101] Editorial, ‘Funding to fight cartels “inadequate”’, Australian Financial Review (Sydney), 11 May 2006, 12; Hodgekiss, above n 40, 11.

[102] ‘Billionaire knew he was guilty’, The Age, 17 October 2007, 1.

[103] Harding and Joshua, above n 6, 280-283.

[104] C. Parker, ‘The “Compliance Trap”: The Moral Message in Responsive Regulatory Enforcement’ (2006) 40(3) Law & Society Review 591, 613.

[105] Media statement by Chris Bowen, Shadow Minister for Revenue & Competition Policy, 9 October 2007 at http://www.alp.org.au/media/1007/msat090.php [Accessed 9 October 2007].

[106] Riley, above n 5, 5.


AustLII: Copyright Policy | Disclaimers | Privacy Policy | Feedback
URL: http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/UMelbLRS/2008/4.html