Home
| Databases
| WorldLII
| Search
| Feedback
Court of Appeal of New Zealand |
Last Updated: 6 November 2019
FOR A COURT READY (FEE REQUIRED) VERSION PLEASE FOLLOW THIS LINK
PUBLIC VERSION
IN THE COURT OF APPEAL OF NEW ZEALAND
I TE KŌTI PĪRA O AOTEAROA
CA92/2018 [2018] NZCA 389
BETWEEN
|
NZME LIMITED
First Appellant
FAIRFAX MEDIA LIMITED Second Appellant
STUFF LIMITED Third Appellant
|
AND
|
COMMERCE COMMISSION Respondent
|
Hearing:
|
5–8 June 2018
|
Court:
|
Kós P, Miller and Asher JJ
|
Counsel:
|
D J Goddard QC, S C Keene, A S Butler and AJWO Lomas for
Appellants
J A Farmer QC, J D Every-Palmer QC, F J Cuncannon, PIC Comrie-Thomson and G
C Spittle for Respondent
|
Judgment:
|
26 September 2018 at 4.00 pm
|
JUDGMENT OF THE COURT
A The appeal is dismissed.
We certify for second
counsel.
NZME LIMITED v COMMERCE COMMISSION [2018] NZCA 389 [26 September
2018]
REASONS OF THE COURT
(Given by Miller J)
Table of Contents
The parties’ businesses and the transaction [6] The decisions below, in brief [15] The structure of this judgment [21] Media plurality and quality [25] Does the Act recognise only public benefits of an economic kind? [31] Salient provisions [31] Legislative history of the Act [35] The Act’s objectives [43] The authorities on public benefit [54] New Zealand practice [55] Australian practice compared [66] Public benefit: conclusions [69] Measuring benefits and detriments [82] “Likely” benefits and detriments [83] The ‘single owner risk’ [90] Objective, transparent and rigorous reasoning required [95] Adequacy of the Commission’s methodology [99] Were the Commission and the High Court wrong on the merits? [107] Quality detriments [109] Plurality [121] The paywall issue [127] The balancing exercise [133] Result [138]
[1] NZME Ltd and Stuff Ltd (formerly Fairfax New Zealand Ltd; we will
call it Fairfax for convenience) publish between them
New Zealand’s major
daily newspapers, Sunday papers and news websites, and a large number of
community newspapers. Their
business model is being disrupted by digital media
and their advertising revenues and subscriber numbers are in sharp decline. They
say that they wish to merge to better navigate their transition to a world
dominated by digital media.
[2] The Commerce Commission found that the transaction would substantially lessen competition in markets for the supply of online national news, for Sunday newspapers and advertising in them, and for community newspapers in ten centres and for advertising in them. It denied the parties an authorisation under s 67 of
the Commerce Act 1986.1 The Commission accepted that the
transaction would deliver substantial and quantifiable public benefits in the
form of productive
efficiency gains for the merged firm, but it found that these
were outweighed by losses in quality and of media “plurality”,
by
which is meant, broadly speaking, the number and diversity of views offered to
the public. Media plurality contributes to the
quality of public discourse and
the health of a democracy, and so benefits the entire
community.2
[3] The High Court (Dobson J and Professor Richardson) dismissed an
appeal.3
The Court agreed that the transaction would substantially lessen
competition in relevant markets.4 It also denied an authorisation,
agreeing with the Commission that losses in media plurality and quality
outweighed the transaction’s
public benefits.
[4] This second appeal is brought by leave of the High Court.5
When granting leave Dobson J identified the following
questions:
(a) Was the High Court correct, as a matter of law, to find
that the Commission has jurisdiction to take into account
non-economic,
unquantified detriments (in the form of plurality concerns) when applying the
legal test for authorisation under s
67(3) of the Act?
(b) Did the High Court err in law and fact in applying the statutory
test of whether the unquantified quality detriments and
plurality detriments
identified by the Commission were “likely”, and were attributable to
the transaction?
(c) Did the High Court err in law and fact in its approach to balancing unquantifiable detriments against the net quantified benefits of
the transaction?
1 NZME Ltd and Fairfax New Zealand Ltd [2017] NZCC 8 [CC determination].
2 We explain what is meant by plurality in more detail at [25] below.
3 NZME Ltd v Commerce Commission [2017] NZHC 3186 [HC judgment]. The appellants also pursued challenges on natural justice grounds in the High Court, but those challenges are not pursued in this appeal.
4 With one exception, the market for advertising in Sunday newspapers. Nothing turns on this conclusion.
5 Commerce Act 1986, s 97; and NZME Ltd v Commerce Commission [2018] NZHC 216.
[5] We were told that this is the first case in which a public good,
such as media plurality, has tipped the scales in an authorisation
application
under the Act. It poses important questions. The appellants say that the
Commission and High Court could not take non-economic
detriments into account at
all; that the High Court wrongly took into account a detriment, the risk of a
single owner exploiting
the merged entity for political purposes, that it
adjudged unlikely to happen; and further, that the Commission and the
High
Court made no adequate attempt to measure loss of plurality, contrary to what
this Court said in Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce
Commission (AMPS-A (CA)).6 These are ultimately
questions of law. They require that we examine the purposes of the authorisation
mechanism and the Act itself.
Finally, the appellants say the Commission was
wrong, and so was the High Court, to decide that the transaction would not
result
in a net benefit to the public. This is a question of fact and
degree.
The parties’ businesses and the transaction
[6] NZME and Fairfax accept the High Court’s concise
summary of their businesses and the proposed transaction.7 In what
follows we substantially adopt that summary.
[7] NZME is a media and entertainment business. It produces print publications, namely The New Zealand Herald, the Herald on Sunday and the Weekend Herald, and digital publications, including nzherald.co.nz. It owns and operates radio broadcasting businesses, including Newstalk ZB, ZM and Radio Hauraki, and it provides other e-commerce services. NZME also has ownership interests in other newspaper and publishing companies. Its businesses are located in the North Island and include six daily newspapers, two paid weekly papers, 11 online versions of newspaper websites, two lifestyle websites, 10 radio station websites, 16 other websites, six magazines, nine radio stations, and 23 community newspapers. NZME was formerly known as
Wilson and Horton Ltd, and it is listed on the
NZX.
7 HC judgment, above n 3, at [3]–[13].
[8] Fairfax is a New Zealand subsidiary of the Australian media company, Fairfax Media Ltd (Fairfax Media), the second appellant. Fairfax produces numerous print publications, operates websites, tablet and smartphone apps for stuff.co.nz, and holds additional media interests through shareholdings in other newspaper publishers. It also operates a website providing a private neighbourhood forum for neighbours to talk and share online. Fairfax’s principal newspapers include The Dominion Post, The Press and the Sunday Star-Times. It publishes nine daily newspapers (of which four are in the North Island and five in the South Island), three paid weekly papers, seven websites, 62 community publications spread throughout the country, and
10 magazines. Fairfax Media is listed on the ASX.
[9] The High Court recorded that the transaction would involve NZME
acquiring all of the shares in Fairfax. In exchange NZME
would pay NZD 55
million in cash and would issue shares equal to a 41 per cent
shareholding in NZME to a wholly-owned
Australian subsidiary of Fairfax
Media. We note in passing that the transaction has now lapsed. The appeal is
not moot, however.
It will determine whether the parties may renew their
agreement.
[10] The High Court observed that the internet has exposed traditional
media businesses to new forms and sources of competition.
It identified two.
The first comprises major newspapers worldwide, which provide international news
and other content that is
available, free or behind a paywall, to New Zealand
consumers. The Court explained that direct consumer access to international
news sources means there is now no New Zealand market confined to
producers of international news. Competition analysis
accordingly focuses on
the production of news, opinions and other information concerning New
Zealand.
[11] The second comprises news aggregators, which do not generate content but collate and redistribute news and information produced by others. Facebook, a social media platform, and Google, which is principally a search engine, dominate. They collate news and information constantly and tailor the content they offer according to the viewer’s algorithmically-predicted areas of interest.
[12] Digital competition for consumer attention to news and information
has disrupted traditional media, sharply reducing the circulation
of printed
publications. Such publications sell both information of interest to readers,
such as news or opinion, and space for advertisers
to market their products. As
circulation falls so does revenue from sales of both the printed products and
the advertising displayed
in them.
[13] The High Court explained that the appellants have responded by
establishing their own websites to supplement their
print publications
and by adopting a “digital-first” news strategy, meaning that
content is posted first on their
digital sites (nzherald.co.nz for NZME and
stuff.co.nz for Fairfax), with a sub-set of the items posted since the last
print publication
being selected for publication in their daily
newspapers.
[14] The appellants’ revenue losses from falling circulation of
printed products have been offset to some extent by revenue
from their own
websites or apps. On these digital platforms the appellants’ revenue
streams are unbundled. Neither appellant
presently uses a paywall, so readers
do not pay to view. Advertising is the only source of revenue. It has been
growing at a rapid
rate, but as yet it is by no means sufficient to offset
falling revenue from printed publications.
The decisions below, in brief
[15] As mentioned above, the Commission found that there would be a
substantial lessening of competition in several relevant markets.8
For this reason it denied a clearance under s 67. That decision, which
was upheld by the High Court, is not challenged in this appeal.
[16] To secure an authorisation, the appellants had to satisfy the Commission that the transaction’s likely public benefits would outweigh its likely adverse effects on competition and the public interest. When assessing effects, the Commission adopted a single counterfactual that comprised two alternative scenarios predicting how the
merged entity would behave compared to the separate businesses. It
recognised that
8 CC determination, above n 1, at [375]–[378], [514]–[518], [705]–[709], [1000] and [1011].
media markets are undergoing rapid change.9 In the first
scenario (digital and print), it assumed that the businesses (whether merged or
separate) would maintain roughly the
same mix of digital and print publications.
In the second scenario (digital and limited print), it assumed that the
businesses (again
whether merged or separate) would scale back their print
publications and instead focus on increasing production of digital
news.10
[17] The appellants identified very substantial benefits, principally taking the form of productive efficiency gains. The Commission accepted that efficiency gains in the range of around $140 million to $210 million over a five-year period were attributable to the transaction.11 It subtracted quantifiable detriments attributable to a paywall that it found would likely be created. The net quantifiable benefits were around
$47.5 million to $200 million across the same five-year
period.12 Against that, it
identified substantial but unquantifiable detriments in the form of losses of
media quality and plurality. These detriments were
“of such
significance” that they outweighed the quantified net benefits of the
transaction, and the conclusion was “not
finely
balanced”.13
[18] The High Court adopted the same counterfactual. It agreed with the Commission that the transaction would substantially lessen competition in relevant markets, except the market for advertising in Sunday newspapers.14 It did not think it likely that a paywall would be built following the transaction.15
The Commission disputes this finding on appeal.
[19] However, the High Court agreed that the transaction would likely result in substantial losses of media quality and plurality.16 It found that a particular risk associated with plurality, the risk that a single owner of the merged firm would exploit
its control for political purposes, was remote but nonetheless relevant.
The appellants
9 At [143]–[144]. The appellants abandoned a challenge to the counterfactual in the High Court:
HC judgment, above n 3, at [46].
10 CC determination, above n 1, at [191]–[194] and [1067]–[1079].
11 At [1325] and [1328].
12 At [1326] and [1329].
13 At [1716] and [1737].
14 HC judgment, above n 3, at [175]–[176].
15 At [118]–[123].
16 At [76] and [267].
say that it was an error of law to take a remote risk into account. The Court
found that the Commission was right to decline
authorisation, but its
decision was more emphatic. It would have declined authorisation on quality
grounds even if plurality
concerns were excluded.17
[20] We record that the parties now agree, following the High Court judgment, that the range of quantifiable benefits attributable to the transaction is approximately
$130 million to $200 million over five years. This excludes detriments
associated with a paywall, which would be in the range of
$0 to $[55–65]
million over the same period.18
The structure of this judgment
[21] We approach the issues in the following way. First, we examine the
important concept of media plurality, on which the first
question posed by the
High Court depends. It will be seen that while the parties agree on a definition
they differ on what it means
for the appeal, the appellants saying that
plurality is non-economic and hence irrelevant, and the Commission that it is
substantially
an in-market consideration.
[22] Secondly, we respond to the appellants’ argument that the
Act’s objectives require that “benefit to the
public” be read
down, confining the term to benefits of an economic nature and excluding
distributional considerations. This
is a policy argument founded in part on
the way in which the Commission and courts have interpreted the Act since it was
enacted.
We approach it in this way:
(a) We identify the relevant provisions and review the Act’s legislative history. This review spans a period before and after its enactment in
1986, and it includes the leading judgments.
(b) In light of that history, we decide whether the Act’s objectives
exclude distributional considerations.
(c) We survey the leading authorities on public benefit.
17 At [304]–[306] and [309].
18 We note that the $0 to $[55–65] million range was agreed by the parties.
[23] Thirdly, we respond to the appellants’ arguments about the
Commission’s and the High Court’s methodology.
We approach them in
this way:
(a) We consider whether the High Court was wrong to include in the
balancing exercise a detriment the likelihood of which it
found remote. (That
detriment is the single owner who can and does exploit the merged firm for
political purposes.) We examine what
the Act requires of the Commission and
courts when measuring benefits and detriments, and we consider the burden and
standard of
“proof” in proceedings of this kind. We then decide
whether the High Court was wrong to take that detriment into
account.
(b) We consider whether the Commission’s methodology was
otherwise insufficiently objective, transparent and rigorous.
This criticism
also affects the High Court decision, since it substantially followed
the Commission’s methodology.
[24] Fourthly, we decide whether the High Court and the Commission erred
on the merits when balancing benefits and detriments:
(a) we examine quality detriments resulting from the transaction;
(b) we examine plurality detriments, to the extent not already
reflected in the discussion about quality;
(c) we consider the paywall issue; and
(d) we undertake the balancing exercise.
Media plurality and quality
[25] The Commission adopted a definition of plurality that incorporates both diversity of content and influence over content. It was expressed as an objective: plurality should ensure both that media offer diversity of information, opinions and perspectives, and that no one media owner, or voice, enjoys too much influence over
public opinion and the political agenda.19 The Commission
recognised that plurality has both external and internal dimensions, meaning
respectively diversity across and within
organisations. The definition itself is
uncontroversial.
[26] Quality is closely connected to plurality, but not synonymous; it
includes the range and diversity of views on offer but
also refers to the
breadth, depth and timeliness of investigation, analysis and
presentation, especially of news.
The Commission considered that the
transaction would cause not only a loss of range and diversity but also a
“significant”
reduction in the quality of news offered to
readers.20
[27] We have characterised plurality as a public good, which means
something that a person a) can consume without diminishing
the quantity
available for others and b) cannot practically be excluded from consuming.
Consistent with that, the Commission recognised
that plurality affects all New
Zealanders whether or not they consume news content. For that reason the
Commission described plurality
as an out of market consideration. The
Commission found that it is an in-market consideration too, because it also
affects those
who do consume news.21
[28] Mr Goddard QC, for the appellants, described plurality as a
non-economic factor, as did the High Court when identifying the
questions listed
at [4] above. We did not understand counsel to mean by this that economics has
nothing to say about the subject.
Rather, he argued that plurality concerns
not the economic welfare of consumers but the health and resilience of New
Zealand democracy,
and for that reason it must be managed at a political level.
This is to characterise plurality as substantially, if not entirely,
an out of
market consideration (to use the Commission’s terminology) that is not
appropriately managed under the Act.
[29] We accept that plurality can be characterised as non-economic to the
extent that its effects are felt outside relevant markets
and are not easily
measured in
19 The definition is that of Ofcom, the United Kingdom communications regulator: Ofcom Measurement framework for media plurality: Ofcom’s advice to the Secretary of State for Culture, Media and Sport (5 November 2015) at [2.2].
20 CC determination, above n 1, at [1672].
21 At [77] and [110].
price-quality terms. That is true, for example, of the effects of a single
owner acquiring influence over public opinion and
the political agenda.
However, we share the Commission’s view that plurality is also felt in
relevant markets, although
its effects may be less direct than those of price
and quality. So it is not entirely non-economic, a point which should be borne
in mind when assessing the argument that the Commission had no business taking
it into account.
[30] Plurality cannot be quantified. The Commission followed the approach
of the English communications regulator, Ofcom, under
which plurality is
estimated using the number of different news sources on media platforms, the
number of consumers using different
sources across all platforms and the
frequency with which they do so, the influence of news consumption on opinion,
and contextual
factors such as the regulatory framework for news media.22
We return to the topic of measurement at [95] below, when examining the
appellants’ arguments that the Commission ought to have
analysed plurality
more rigorously.
Does the Act recognise only public benefits of an economic
kind?
Salient provisions
[31] We confine ourselves to the immediately relevant provisions.
Section 66 provides that the Commission may grant a clearance
for a business
acquisition if satisfied that it will not have the effect of substantially
lessening competition in a market.23 We will call this an SLC for
brevity. Under s 67 it may authorise a transaction that would cause an
SLC:
67 Commission may grant authorisations for business
acquisitions
(1) A person who proposes to acquire assets of a business or shares
may give the Commission a notice seeking an authorisation
for the
acquisition.
...
22 Ofcom, above n 19.
23 Section 47 of the Commerce Act prohibits a business acquisition where it would substantially lessen competition in a market, and the words “business” and “acquire” are defined in s 2 of the Act. The phrase “lessening of competition” is not defined, except to say that lessening
includes hindering or preventing: s 3(2).
(3) Within 60 working days after the date of registration of the
notice, or such longer period as the Commission and the person
who gave the
notice agree, the Commission shall—
(a) if it is satisfied that the acquisition will not have, or would
not be likely to have, the effect of substantially lessening
competition in a
market, by notice in writing to the person by or on whose behalf the notice was
given, give a clearance for the
acquisition; or
(b) if it is satisfied that the acquisition will result, or will be
likely to result, in such a benefit to the public that
it should be permitted,
by notice in writing to the person by or on whose behalf the notice was given,
grant an authorisation for
the acquisition; or
(c) if it is not satisfied as to the matters referred to in paragraph
(a) or paragraph (b), by notice in writing to the person
by or on whose behalf
the notice was given, decline to give a clearance or grant an authorisation for
the acquisition.
[32] The term “benefit to the public” is not defined,
but s 3A provides that efficiencies are mandatory
relevant considerations
when deciding whether such benefit is likely to result from conduct:
3A Commission to consider efficiency
Where the Commission is required under this Act to determine whether
or not, or the extent to which, conduct will result,
or will be likely to
result, in a benefit to the public, the Commission shall have regard to any
efficiencies that the Commission
considers will result, or will be likely to
result, from that conduct.
[33] The Act’s purpose statement provides:24
1A Purpose
The purpose of this Act is to promote competition in markets for the
long-term benefit of consumers within New Zealand.
[34] “[C]ompetition” means workable or effective competition,25 and “market”
refers to New Zealand goods and services markets the boundaries of which are
gauged by applying, as matters of fact and common sense,
the concept of
substitutability.26
24 Section 1A was inserted, on 26 May 2001, by s 4 of the Commerce Amendment Act 2001.
As originally enacted the Commerce Act had a long title which provided that it was “An Act to promote competition in markets within New Zealand”, but that long title was repealed by the Commerce Amendment Act. We discuss this legislative history in further detail below at [47].
25 Commerce Act, s 3(1).
26 Section 3(1A).
The concept of “workable” or “effective” competition
is traced, via Re Queensland
Co-operative Milling Association Ltd (QCMA),27
to the 1955 Report of the
United States Attorney-General’s National Committee to Study the
Antitrust Laws:28
The basic characteristic of effective competition in the economic sense is
that no one seller, and no group of sellers acting in concert,
has the power to
choose its level of profits by giving less and charging more. Where there is
workable competition, rival sellers,
whether existing competitors or new or
potential entrants into the field, would keep this power in check by offering or
threatening
to offer effective inducements ...
Legislative history of the Act
[35] As is well-known, the Act is based on the Trade Practices Act 1974
(Cth), which in turn is derived from the Sherman Antitrust Act (US) and Clayton
Antitrust Act (US).29 The Australasian statutes reoriented
competition law in both jurisdictions. Predecessor legislation — in New
Zealand’s
case, the Commerce Act 1975 — had generally followed an
English model that30 did not create absolute prohibitions but
required that restrictive trade practices be registered and approved if they
were in the
public interest or restrained if they were
not.31
[36] The Sherman Act prohibits outright every “contract, combination ... or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce”.32 It was traditionally used to restrain mergers to monopoly,33 but mergers are now addressed under the Clayton Act, which
prohibits mergers that may substantially lessen competition or
tend to create a
27 Re Queensland Co-operative Milling Association Ltd [1976] 25 FLR 169 (Australian Trade
Practices Tribunal) at 188 [QCMA].
28 Stanley N Barnes and S Chesterfield Oppenheim Report of the United States Attorney-General’s National Committee to Study the Antitrust Laws (United States Department of Justice, March 1955) at 320. The concept is further traceable to the work of the Harvard economist Edward S Mason: see the discussion in Alan J Meese “Debunking the Purchaser Welfare
Account of Section 2 of the Sherman Act: How Harvard Brought Us a Total Welfare Standard
and Why We Should Keep It” (2010) 85 NYU L Rev 659 at 692–693.
29 Sherman Antitrust Act 15 USC § 1–7 (1890); and Clayton Antitrust Act 15 USC § 12–27, 29
USC § 52–53 (1914). See Mark N Berry “New Zealand Antitrust: Some Reflections on the First
Twenty-Five Years” (2013) 10 Loy U Chi Int Law Rev 125 at 126.
30 Restrictive Trade Practices Act 1956 (UK).
31 Department of Trade and Industry Commerce Bill 1985: A Background to the Bill and An Outline to its Provisions (August 1985) at 7–8.
32 15 USC § 1.
33 Northern Securities Co v United States [1904] USSC 64; 193 US 197 (1904); Standard Oil Co of New Jersey v
United States [2004] USSC 1; 221 US 1 (1911) [Standard Oil]; and United States v First National Bank & Trust
Co of Lexington [1964] USSC 73; 376 US 665 (1964).
monopoly.34 The standard under both statutes is usually
considered to be the same.35
Courts have long held that while some practices are per se unlawful, others
must be evaluated under a “rule of reason”.36 The rule
of reason focuses on the impact on competition of the restraint in question, and
does not permit consideration of other social
or economic goals.37
The legislation contains no authorisation mechanism, which distinguishes
it from its New Zealand counterpart.
[37] Three points should be made about the decision to adopt a model
founded on
US antitrust law:
(a) The impetus for reform was the desire to direct the economy toward
more competition and greater efficiency.38 It was also considered
important to harmonise New Zealand and Australian law.39
(b) Officials recognised that small economies must sometimes tolerate
levels of market concentration that would be considered
anticompetitive
elsewhere if they are to overcome diseconomies of scale and the costs of
competing in distant markets.40
(c) The adoption of a new model engendered resistance in the business community, which feared substantive uncertainty and unpredictability in the law. This concern was associated with transition from a prescriptive, rules-based regime, in which many restrictive trade
practices were not per se illegal but might be registered and
authorised,
34 15 USC § 13(a).
35 United States v Rockford Memorial Corp 898 F 2d 1278 (7th Cir) (1990) at 1281–1282.
36 Standard Oil, above n 33.
37 National Society of Professional Engineers v United States [1978] USSC 67; 435 US 679 (1978) at 681 and 688;
National Collegiate Athletic Association v Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma
[1984] USSC 155; 468 US 85 (1984) at 107 and 113; Arizona v Maricopa County Medical Society [1982] USSC 122; 457 US 332 (1982); Federal Trade Commission v Indiana Federation of Dentists [1986] USSC 113; 476 US 447 (1986); and Federal Trade Commission v Superior Court Trial Lawyers Assoc [1990] USSC 12; 493 US 411 (1990).
38 Department of Trade and Industry, above n 31, at 3 and 10.
39 At 4.
40 Trade Practices Act Review Committee Report to the Minister for Business and Consumer Affairs (August 1976) at [11.11]. Berry notes that New Zealand markets are characterised by high concentration levels, high entry barriers and inefficient levels of production: Berry, above
n 29, at 127–128 and 146–147.
to a behavioural regime in which such practices might be adjudged illegal
after the fact and under broadly-expressed standards.
[38] An authorisation mechanism was incorporated to address these concerns and ensure that other public policy objectives might be balanced against competition.41
It is not a mere incident of the legislation but a central feature. It
applies to both business acquisitions and restrictive trade
practices, allowing
firms to obtain approval in advance for transactions that would cause an SLC but
offer some offsetting public
benefit.42 It draws from English,
American and Australian tradition, combining what a contemporary commentator
described (among other things)
as a self-regulating statute incorporating public
benefit analysis before specialist tribunals.43
[39] As originally implemented in Australia, an authorisation required
that the arrangement concerned would result in a “substantial”
public benefit that “would not otherwise be available”.44
This standard was thought too restrictive, and following the report of the
Swanson Committee the legislation was amended in 1977 to
require simply that the
arrangement would be likely to result in a public benefit outweighing any
lessening of competition.45 The Committee explained that:
11.11 ... It seems to the Committee that it is generally accepted in the
Australian environment, and in regard to the size of the
market and the size of
economic units operating in that market in at least some industries, that there
will be cases in which the
community accepts that public benefit or public
interest considerations should justify the existence of restrictions on
competition.
[40] Having concluded that the existing authorisation test was
too harsh,
the Committee emphasised that competition must remain the legislation’s primary objective but authorisation should be available where it could be shown that the
transaction would result in benefits to the
public:
41 Department of Trade and Industry, above n 31, at 22.
43 Bruce G Donald and JD Heydon Trade Practices Law (The Law Book Co, Sydney, 1978) at 11.
44 See as enacted Trade Practices Act 1974 (Cth), s 90(5).
transactions that had not been authorised might be found unlawful: at [11.8].
11.15 ... However, if in a given case it can be shown that public benefits,
i.e. not merely benefits to the parties to the restrictive
conduct, are
available, and that those benefits outweigh the benefits to the public foregone
by the absence or restriction of competition,
then that conduct should be
permitted to continue.
It will be seen that the Committee distinguished benefits to the public, who
would experience the transaction’s loss of benefits,
from private benefits
to the parties.
[41] In the meantime, the Trade Practices Tribunal (the Australian
Tribunal) had delivered its famous decision in QCMA, in which it
explained the concept of public benefit in the broadest
terms:46
One question that arises is whether by the public is meant the consuming
public. One submission to us was that, in the context of
the objectives of the
Act, we should direct our attention to that part of the public concerned with
the use or consumption of flour
in the Queensland market.
...
However this is not what the Australian Act says; and we cannot but think
that the choice of a wider expression was deliberate, as
pointing to some wider
conception of the public interest, though no doubt the interests of the public
as purchasers, consumers or
users must fall within it and bulk large.
Another question raised is whether public benefit must be contrasted with
private benefit. Can a benefit to some of the private parties
to the merger
— for example the shareholders of Barnes — be claimed as a public
benefit? Must a benefit which accrues
to the private parties be “passed
on” to members of the wider community before it can be considered? The
commission
has expressed its view ... that the test requires “benefits to
the public and not merely to the applicant or some other limited
group”.
While agreeing with this statement as far as it goes, we would not wish to rule
out of consideration any argument
coming within the widest possible conception
of public benefit. This we see as anything of value to the community generally,
any
contribution to the aims pursued by the society including as one of its
principal elements (in the context of trade practices legislation)
the
achievement of the economic goals of efficiency and progress.
(Citation omitted.)
[42] As noted, harmonisation with Australian law was among the
motivations for the Act. Its authorisation test was materially
identical to
that in the Trade Practices
46 QCMA, above n 27, at 182–183. The names of the relevant bodies in Australia have changed names over the years. We refer to the body currently known as the Australian Competition Tribunal as “the Australian Tribunal” and the body currently known as the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission as “the Australian Commission”.
Act.47 Officials must be taken to have known that QCMA
and the work of the
Swanson Committee had preceded the 1977 amendments to the Trade Practices
Act.
The Act’s objectives
[43] Mr Goddard argued that the Commission must, and usually does, adopt
a “total welfare” approach, under which a
transaction’s
benefits and detriments are valued equally regardless of who receives or incurs
them. This argument rests on
the proposition that the Act’s objectives
exclude distributional considerations, by which is meant a preference for one
class
of beneficiary over another, or for widely dispersed benefits over those
retained by the parties to a given transaction.
[44] Total welfare takes aggregate economic efficiency to be the
law’s objective and seeks to maximise it. So producer
surplus is treated
as a welfare gain because the surplus is available for use elsewhere in the
economy,48 and the distribution of gains and losses is discounted
because distribution has no bearing on efficiency. Total welfare
draws no
distinction between gains from a transaction that are “private” in
the sense that they accrue to the suppliers
who are parties to it and those that
are “public” in the sense that they accrue to a class of
consumers.
[45] There is a longstanding normative debate about whether total welfare ought to be the objective of antitrust law.49 The alternative is the consumer welfare approach, which when narrowly defined looks to the share of gains that goes to consumers and excludes gains to producers in the same market.50 The rationale for admitting distributive considerations is sometimes expressed in fairness terms — consumers
should receive public benefits associated with restrictive trade
practices because they
47 Compare as at 1986 Commerce Act, s 67(5); and Trade Practices Act, s 90(6). We observe that the Department of Trade and Industry referred to Australian case law when explaining what was meant by “a substantial lessening of competition” in practice: Department of Trade and Industry, above n 31, at 12.
48 We define producer and consumer surplus following Oliver Williamson: see Oliver E Williamson “Economies as an Antitrust Defense: the Welfare Tradeoffs” (1968) 58 Am Econ Rev 18.
49 The literature is surveyed in Herbert Hovenkamp “Implementing Antitrust’s Welfare Goals”
50 We recognise that consumer welfare has sometimes been defined in terms synonymous with total welfare, notably by Robert Bork, but the definition used here is orthodox and serves our purpose of distinguishing a policy that admits distributional considerations from one that does not. See Robert H Bork The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy At War With Itself (The Free Press,
New York, 1978), at 66, 97 and 107–113.
experience the anticompetitive effects.51 But the underlying
explanation is simply that the law admits non-efficiency values because it
reflects norms of the community that
it serves.52
[46] Mr Goddard is correct that the Commission normally pursues a total
welfare approach. It stated in its 2013 Authorisation Guidelines
(2013 Guidelines),53 and in its former Guidelines
to the Analysis of Public Benefits and Detriments (1997
Guidelines) that distributional effects are generally irrelevant
because the distribution of gains and losses does not affect
efficiency.54
[47] This emphasis on total welfare emerged in New Zealand in the 1990s. The legislation was amended in 1990 to insert s 3A; as noted above, it requires that when examining public benefits the Commission must “have regard to” efficiencies likely to result from the conduct in question.55 Hampton and Scott explain that the
1990 amendment followed a series of Commission decisions discounting benefits
that were not passed to consumers.56
[48] In 1994 the Commission first issued its Guidelines to the
Analysis of Public Benefits and Detriments.57 The guidelines
followed a 1992 interdepartmental review and proposed legislation — never
enacted — that would have required
that when assessing public benefit
the Commission must treat efficiency as the primary consideration and
ignore distributional
effects. These norms were reflected in the
guidelines.58
[49] In 2001 the purpose statement was amended to specify in s 1A, as
noted above, that the Act’s purpose is “to promote
competition in
markets for the long-term benefit
51 John Duns “Competition Law and Public Benefits” [1994] AdelLawRw 7; (1994) 16 Adel L Rev 245 at 255.
52 Herbert Hovenkamp “Distributive Justice and the Antitrust Laws” (1982) 51 Geo Wash L Rev 1
at 4 and 16–27. See also Richard A Posner The Economics of Justice (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, 1981).
53 Commerce Commission Authorisation Guidelines (July 2013) at [53] [2013 Guidelines].
54 Commerce Commission Guidelines to the Analysis of Public Benefits and Detriments
(December 1997) at 14 [1997 Guidelines].
55 Commerce Amendment Act 1990, s 4.
56 Lindsay Hampton and Paul G Scott Guide to Competition Law (LexisNexis, Wellington, 2013)
at 3.
58 Hampton and Scott, above n 56, at 3.
of consumers within New Zealand”.59 Professor Ahdar suggested that the Bill stemmed from the desire of the government of the day to emphasise consumer welfare out of concern that it had been neglected in Commission and judicial decisions.60
The parliamentary record supports that view. Speaking to the Bill, the then
Minister of Commerce, the Hon Paul Swain, said:61
[The purpose statement] makes clear that competition is not an end in itself,
but a means to promote the welfare of New Zealanders.
Consumers are given
special mention as they are the ultimate beneficiaries of competition. However,
the welfare of all New Zealanders
will continue to be important. This is an
important aspect of the change, and brings us closer into line with the
equivalent legislation
in Australia. The focus on competition in the purpose
statement also does not preclude wider public benefit issues being taking
into
account where appropriate. It simply clarifies that there should be a
presumption in favour of competition, and competition
must prevail unless the
efficiencies of other public benefits are shown to exceed the detriments from
the lessening of competition.
[50] The Commerce Committee expressed concern that by referring
to the “long term” the amendment might lead
the Commission to
overemphasise dynamic efficiency at the expense of more immediate benefits, but
it found the term acceptable on
the basis that welfare meant consumer
welfare.62 A reference to facilitating the “efficient
operation of markets” was also removed by the Committee.63 In
the House the Chairman of the Committee, David Cunliffe, stated
that:64
Members will forgive me if I provide a little context about an academic debate that has raged for some years between those who support an efficiency test ... the so-called Chicago School, and those who seek a welfare-based test, the
so-called Harvard School. This purpose statement makes it clear that the
New Zealand Parliament supports a welfare-based, Harvard School approach that puts the interest of consumers first. However, we have taken due account
of the arguments that we have to take a long-term perspective and see dynamic
efficiency play in the market, and for that reason it is the long-term
interests of consumers that appear in the new purpose statement.
[51] In its 2004 judgment in Air New Zealand v Commerce Commission (No
6)
the High Court referred to the 2001 amendment and rejected a submission
that under
59 See above at [33].
60 Rex Ahdar “Consumers, redistribution of income and the purpose of competition law” (2002)
23 ECLR 341 at 341–342.
61 (27 February 2001) 590 NZPD 7972.
62 Commerce Amendment Bill 296-2 (select committee report) at 7.
63 At 7.
64 (27 February 2001) 590 NZPD 7975.
s 1A the only relevant public benefits are those that flow directly to
consumers.65
Rather, the Court endorsed the Commission’s by then established
total welfare approach and accepted that the distributional
effects of a merger
are irrelevant:
[241] We are satisfied that the introduction of s 1A should not disturb
the Commission’s established practice of treating
as neutral any
wealth transfers between New Zealand consumers and producers. Determinations of
authorisation applications under
the Act are properly concerned with balancing
any efficiency detriments associated with breaches of the statutory competition
standard,
against any efficiency gains that may result from the business
acquisition or contractual arrangement in question. It is the balancing
of these
real resource impacts on the economy that best serves the long-term interests of
consumers. The inclusion of ad hoc wealth
transfers, which are not losses to
society, would distort the efficiency assessment by assuming additional economic
harm to the public
of New Zealand. In any event, consumers might well be the
ultimate beneficiaries.
The Commission has since taken the view that Air New Zealand binds it
to generally follow a total welfare approach when assessing public
benefits.66
[52] It is debateable whether the High Court should be taken to have held
that the Commission must follow an objective that the
Commission had adopted of
its own volition and the Court did not itself evaluate against the legislative
history. The Court inquired
rather whether the new s 1A meant that only direct
consumer benefits counted.
[53] In any event, this Court has never held that the Act compels a total welfare approach. It has long recognised that the Act pursues economic welfare and uses the language of economics; in Tru Tone Ltd v Festival Retail Marketing Ltd (Tru Tone), Richardson J referred to the original purpose statement and said that the Act “is based on the premise that society’s resources are best allocated in a competitive market where rivalry between firms ensures maximum efficiency in the use of resources.”67
To make this general point, though, is not to nominate total welfare as the Act’s objective, still less to question the statutory presumption that competition is the
mechanism through which efficiency gains will be delivered to consumers.
There is
66 CC determination, above n 1, at [1063], citing Air New Zealand, above n 65.
67 Tru Tone Ltd v Festival Records Retail Marketing Ltd [1988] NZCA 179; [1988] 2 NZLR 352 (CA) at 358.
no reason to suppose that when Richardson J spoke of efficiency he had the
distinction between total and consumer welfare in mind.68
The authorities on public benefit
[54] We turn to examine how public benefit has been interpreted in
practice. It will be seen that the term has never been limited
to economic or in
market considerations.
New Zealand practice
[55] We begin with Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce
Commission (AMPS-A (HC)), in which Telecom sought clearance or
authorisation for the acquisition of certain radio frequencies.69
It failed before the Commission and the High Court but succeeded on
further appeal.70 In the High Court judgment is found what is still
the leading New Zealand discussion of public benefit. The Court noted the
Australian
approach,71 citing Re Rural Traders Co-op (WA)
Ltd:72
It is undesirable to attempt to fix in advance the limits of what the concept
of “benefit to the public” encompasses or
to exclude, in advance,
from its ambit any contribution to the legitimate aims pursued by society. In
the context of Trade Practices
legislation, the encouragement of
competition and competitive behaviour within relevant markets and the
achievement of
the economic goals of efficiency and progress will commonly be
paramount. The fact that a particular result of a proposed acquisition
may be
neutral in so far as such behaviour or such economic goals are concerned does
not, however, preclude it from being a relevant
(and, conceivably, a
determining) factor in the assessment of public benefit ...
[56] The Court recognised that in New Zealand s 3A (which had no equivalent in the Australian legislation) compelled regard for any efficiencies, but held that the
section left for case-by-case judgement the weight that should be
assigned to them:73
68 We recognise that there have been other changes to the Act since 1986 which we have not discussed; some of these are surveyed in Commerce Commission v Woolworths Ltd [2008] NZCA 276, (2008) 12 TCLR 194 at [65]–[72] [Woolworths]. However, it was not suggested that these differences are material in this case. Nor was it suggested that the differences in wording between s 61 of the Act and s 67 are material.
69 Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce Commission (1991) 4 TCLR 473 (HC)
[AMPS-A (HC)]. The Court comprised Greig J, W J Shaw and Professor M Brunt.
70 AMPS-A (CA), above n 6.
71 AMPS-A (HC), above n 69, at 527.
72 Re Rural Traders Co-op (WA) Ltd (1979) ATPR 40-110 (Trade Practices Tribunal) at 18,123 [Rural Traders].
73 AMPS-A (HC), above n 69, at 528.
The new section compels regard to any efficiencies that will likely result
from the acquisition, but what weight will be given to
them, either in relation
to other potential elements of public benefit or in relation to public
detriment, must be a matter of judgment
in the particular case. We bear in mind
that efficiency has three dimensions commonly referred to as allocative
efficiency, production
efficiency, and dynamic efficiency. Efficiency
considerations, positive and negative, are relevant in the assessment of both
benefit
and detriment but clearly do not exhaust society’s interest in the
business conduct the subject of the Commerce Act.
Accordingly, the Australian approach to public benefit was
applicable in New Zealand. The Court envisaged that distributional
concerns
could be of significant or even determinative weight.74
[57] Addressing Telecom’s claim that efficiency gains need not be
passed on to consumers, the Court elaborated on the concept
of public
benefit:75
Thus the distinction customarily drawn is between public benefit and private
benefit (or private motivation), between social value
and private value, when
there is market failure in an extended sense. Public benefit has been found in
the very nature of
the conduct for which authorisation is
sought (e.g. “professional” standards of work and
acceptance
of fiduciary responsibility) ... in the use of a non-market
process to organise an activity (e.g. cooperative enterprise) ...
and in
dimensions of market performance that include static and dynamic efficiency but
go beyond them (e.g. the protection of children
from some kinds of
advertisement)...
(Citations omitted.)
[58] The Court went on to accept that public benefit includes efficiency
gains; further, that may be true even if little or none
of the benefit is passed
to consumers. It cautioned, however, that in such a case it may be necessary to
inquire whether the gains
are durable or may be frittered away through slackness
and rent-seeking activities:76
It is important in assessing the magnitude of these benefits, in our view, to
focus not so much on their immediate distribution as
on their durability. Where
efficiency gains are not “passed on to the consumer”, there may be a
question that requires
inquiry as to whether, or to what extent, the lack of
competitive pressure will allow the productivity gains to be frittered away
in
slackness and wasteful “rent-seeking”
activities.
74 At 530.
75 At 529–530.
76 At 530.
[59] This Court allowed the appeal, but it did not take a different view
of the concept of public benefit.77 In a well-known passage about
methodology to which we must return, Richardson J noted that the relevant
benefits and detriments were
almost entirely efficiency gains and no issue arose
about quantifying and weighing “disparate public interest
considerations”.78
[60] For its part, the Commission has consistently accepted that an
applicant for an authorisation may invoke public benefits
of any kind. It is
sufficient for our purposes to cite the 2013 Guidelines applied in this
case.79 They state, invoking the judgments in AMPS-A (HC),
Air New Zealand, and Godfrey Hirst NZ Ltd v Commerce Commission
(Godfrey Hirst (No 1)),80 that a public benefit is
anything of value to the community generally, that the term includes but is not
limited to efficiencies,
and that the Commission recognises as a public benefit
any gain to the public of New Zealand that would result from the proposed
transaction regardless of the market in which that benefit occurs or who it
benefits.81 Benefits are assessed net of any disbenefits
associated with them.82
[61] We pause here to note that, as the Commission submitted, if in pursuit of economic efficiency the Act excludes non-economic considerations from s 67, then it must follow that the Commission was wrong in other cases to consider the following benefits: reduced pollution,83 health benefits of breastfeeding,84 safer handling of hazardous substances,85 reduced stigma for psychiatric patients,86 and social effects of
plant closures.87
77 AMPS-A (CA), above n 6. We return to this Court’s reasoning in the case at [96] below.
78 At 447.
the same approach.
80 AMPS-A (HC), above n 69, at 528; Air New Zealand, above n 65, at [319]; and Godfrey Hirst
NZ Ltd v Commerce Commission (2011) 9 NZBLC 103,396 (HC) at [51] [Godfrey Hirst (No 1)].
81 2013 Guidelines, above n 53, at [35]–[37].
82 At [38] n 32.
83 Nelson City Council and Tasman District Council [2017] NZCC 6 at [111]–[112].
84 Infant Nutrition Council Ltd [2015] NZCC 11 at [69]–[71].
85 Refrigerant Licence Trust Board CC Decision No 735, 25 November 2011 at [77]–[81].
86 Midland Regional Health Authority and Health Waikato Ltd CC Decision No 275, 1 August
1995 at [318] and [323]–[336].
[62] The 2013 Guidelines
approach detriments in an asymmetric manner, counting only
“anti-competitive detriments that arise in the market(s) where we
find a
lessening of competition”.88 This suggests that any detriments
of a non-economic or non-market nature are excluded. For this approach the
guidelines cite Godfrey Hirst (No 1) and observations of Wilson J
in this Court in New Zealand Bus Ltd v Commerce
Commission.89 Ultimately, however, these
authorities rest on the Commission’s own practice. In Godfrey
Hirst (No 1),90 the Court said that this practice had been
sanctioned by the High Court and this Court in AMPS-A.91 We
do not agree. The practice was not in issue in AMPS-A and it is drawing
too long a bow to read an endorsement into the judgments.
[63] This Court returned to the topic of public benefit in its 2016
judgment in Godfrey Hirst NZ Ltd v Commerce Commission (Godfrey Hirst
(No 2)), stating after reference to the legislative history and the judgment
in AMPS-A (HC) that the concept includes non-economic benefits and
detriments:92
The legislative history shows Parliament’s intention to leave this
category [authorisation of business acquisitions] open for
the
Commission’s expert assessment ... While the benefits are not confined to
the particular market, the Commission and the
courts must take account of the
values or public interest at stake in that particular market when determining
benefits or detriments
to the wider public, especially when economic activity
can have negative consequences for others and many social goods and services
are
now distributed through market mechanisms ...
(Footnotes omitted.)
[64] In its determination in this case the Commission relied on media plurality, which it characterised in part as an out of market detriment. It did not find this inconsistent with the 2013 Guidelines, which it described as general and necessarily
non-exhaustive.93 In any event, the
guidelines had not been updated following
88 2013 Guidelines, above n 53, at [38].
89 Godfrey Hirst (No 1), above n 80, at [72]; and New Zealand Bus Ltd v Commerce Commission
[2007] NZCA 502, [2008] 3 NZLR 433 at [271].
90 Godfrey Hirst (No 1), above n 80, at [72].
91 AMPS-A (HC), above n 69; and AMPS-A (CA), above n 6.
Godfrey Hirst (No 2). Citing QCMA, the
Commission reasoned that were it to ignore out of market detriments it might act
against the public interest:
80. ... there would be a category of negative consequences of a
proposed merger that we are required to ignore. For example,
if a merger was to
have an adverse impact on the environment, employment, privacy interests, or
other constituents of social welfare
which fall outside of the market(s) in
which competition has been lessened or else are not efficiency related, we would
be required
to ignore those factors in assessing whether there was such a public
benefit that the transaction should be permitted.
81. The implication of the Applicants’ approach is that we might
have to authorise a merger that in our assessment was
not in the public
interest. That is, if we considered that there was a negative
consequence that outweighed the positive
aspects of a proposed merger, we might
still have to authorise depending on where those negative impacts were
felt.
82. It is difficult to discern a rationale for
Parliament wanting the Commission to consider only some of
the detriments to
the public of a merger and to disregard others, and we would only adopt such an
approach if compelled to do so
by the statutory language, or judicial
interpretation of the Act.
83. In our view, the language of the Act does not compel the
interpretation that some negative consequences count for the purposes
of the
analysis and some do not. To the contrary, we consider that our statutory task
is to determine whether the merger will be
likely to result “in such a
benefit to the public that it should be permitted” notwithstanding that
the merger has the
effect or likely effect of substantially lessening
competition. Whether there is such a ‘benefit to the public’ cannot
be considered divorced from outcomes that harm the public, whether or not they
are economic or market-oriented in nature.
[65] The Commission concluded that:
96. ... we would not be giving effect to section 67 if we disregard a
material source of negative consequences. Usually the
approach set out in our
Authorisation Guidelines will be sufficient to capture the dynamics involved in
a proposed acquisition, but
the plurality issue has caused us to carefully
address where the relevant negative consequences should be included in our
analysis.
Australian practice compared
[66] The Australian Commission and Tribunal have not gone so far as the Commission in the pursuit of total welfare. The legislation has never contained a provision corresponding to s 3A and distributional considerations have not been discounted. That said, economic efficiency has been treated as the dominant consideration and it has been accepted in an authorisation setting that efficiencies need
not be passed on to consumers. In its 2004 decision in Qantas
Airways, the Tribunal stated that:94
In our view, the objective and statutory language of the Act, as well as
precedent, support the use of a form of the total welfare
standard as the most
appropriate standard for identifying and assessing public benefit. We say a
“form of” the total
welfare standard because, as the passage cited
from Re Howard Smith shows, whilst the Tribunal does not require that
efficiencies generated by a merger or set of arrangements necessarily be passed
on
to consumers, it may be that, in some circumstances, gains that flow through
only to a limited number of members in the community
will carry less
weight.
[67] In the decision cited in that passage, Re Howard Smith Industries
Pty Ltd, the Tribunal had said, following QCMA,
that:95
The Tribunal has to determine what constitutes “the public” in
order to assess whether there is likely to be a substantial
benefit to the
public from a proposed merger. It is not simply the public as consumers. If a
merger is likely to result in the achievement
of economies of scale and a
considerable saving in the cost of supplying a good or service this might well
constitute a substantial
benefit to the public, even though the cost saving is
not passed on to the consumers in the form of lower prices. Nevertheless, if
such a merger benefited only a small number of shareholders of the applicant
corporations through higher profits and dividends, this
might be given less
weight by the Tribunal, because the benefits are not being spread widely among
members of the community generally.
This has become known as the modified total welfare approach.
[68] In Australian Competition and Consumer Commission v
Australian Competition Tribunal (ACCC) a Full Federal Court recently
held that the current legislation, the Competition and Consumer Act 2010,
permitted but did not require that the Tribunal use the modified total welfare
approach:96
What the Tribunal is required to do is to assess the benefit to the public
resulting, or likely to result from the merger, and to
do so in “all the
circumstances”. Having done that it is to decide whether that benefit
warrants the grant of the
authorisation. That is the statutory
charter it has. Whilst certain matters may be inferred from the language of s
95AZH(1)
as we have outlined above, it is nevertheless a broadly expressed
provision. It is
94 Qantas Airways Ltd [2005] ACompT 9, (2005) ATPR 42-065 at [185] (the decision was released in 2004 but reasons were not delivered until 2005). See also The Hospital Benefit Fund of Western Australia Inc v ACCC (1997) ATPR 41-569 (FCA) at 43,904–43,905; and Rural Traders, above n 72, at 18,123.
95 Re Howard Smith Industries Pty Ltd (1977) ATPR 40-023 (Trade Practices Tribunal) at 17,334.
96 Australian Competition and Consumer Commission v Australian Competition Tribunal [2017] FCAFC 150, (2017) 254 FCR 341 at [67] [ACCC].
a legitimate way for the Tribunal to proceed in assessing the benefit to the
public resulting from a merger to adopt the modified
total welfare standard
identified in Qantas. But the tail must not wag the dog, and it is not
that standard that s 95AZH imposes. Consequently, the reasons of the Tribunal
are to be measured for their legal efficacy against only the text of s 95AZH(1)
and what can be reasonably implied from it, not the
test identified in
Qantas.
Public benefit: conclusions
[69] Having surveyed the legislation, its history, and the authorities,
we can now answer the question whether “benefit
to the public”,
as used in s 67, excludes non-economic or out of market
considerations. The High Court
held that the Commission has jurisdiction
to consider a loss of plurality resulting from the transaction.97
It accepted that out of market considerations may seldom arise and the
Commission may be susceptible to challenge on the merits if
it takes them into
account, but as a matter of construction Parliament cannot have intended to
exclude such considerations where
a proposed transaction is likely to cause
them.98 We agree generally with these conclusions.
[70] Drawing together several threads of the discussion above, we make
several points about the legislation. We confine ourselves
to observations of
relevance to this appeal.
[71] The first concerns efficiency. We accept that the reference to
“long-term benefit” in the purpose statement
recognises that the Act
values efficiency. It also admits the possibility that the pursuit of
efficiency may not benefit consumers
in the short term. Section 3A further
presumes that efficiency gains may benefit the public and prescribes that regard
must be had
to them when assessing public benefit. But as a matter of
construction the Act treats efficiency as a subset of public benefit;
put
another way, efficiency is a mandatory consideration but others are not
excluded. To paraphrase AMPS-A (HC), efficiency matters but it does not
exhaust society’s interest in the transaction.
[72] Second, “benefit to the public” is not defined, although
it sets the standard for authorisation, which for reasons
given at
[37]–[40] above, is an integral feature of the
97 HC judgment, above n 3, at [231].
98 At [210]–[214].
legislative scheme. So the Commission is to decide what benefits the public
in the circumstances of any given case.
[73] The 2001 amendments confirm rather than detract from what was said about public benefit in the passages from AMPS-A (HC) that we have cited above.99
In particular, the Act is not exclusively concerned with efficiency but
rather allows it to be balanced alongside other public benefits
that may include
anything of importance to the community as a whole. Nothing in the legislation
requires that public detriments be
defined less comprehensively. The
identification and weighting of public benefits, including efficiency gains, and
detriments is
left to the Commission’s
judgement.100
[74] Third, from the courts’ perspective this analysis is not
novel. It is consistent with the authorities as we have explained
them. It does
not discount efficiency. On the contrary, this Court recognised in Tru Tone
that workable and effective competition is prized because it delivers
efficiency gains to consumers.101 To modify, by reference to the
2001 amendments, what the Court said there, the Act rests on the premise that
consumers benefit from
competitive markets in which rivalry among firms
maximises efficiency. Efficiency is not confined to the efficient economy-wide
allocation of resources; it includes productive and dynamic efficiency in
relevant markets. In this case public detriments prevailed
over efficiency
benefits, so it bears emphasis that the converse may be true, and often is.
The legislative history confirms Parliament’s
intention that authorisation
should allow efficiency considerations to prevail over an SLC where the
transaction concerned will sufficiently
benefit consumers over time or in other
ways.
[75] Fourth, it follows that the legislation permits the modified total welfare approach discussed at [66]–[67] above. We should not be taken to say, however, that the Commission must follow the modified total welfare approach in practice.
The Commission is equipped to develop policies and guidelines within the
statutory
99 See at [55]–[58] above.
100 Godfrey Hirst (No 2), above n 92, at [22] and [35]. We record that Mr Every-Palmer did not ask the Court to hold that the Commission may value dispersed benefits more. He recognised that the issue had not previously arisen in this case. It is however necessary to respond to the appellants’ argument that distributional considerations, which include the dispersal of benefits, may not be taken into account.
101 Tru Tone, above n 67, at 358.
framework, and it is responsible for doing so. The courts are responsible for
assessing the Commission’s decisions, in law and
on their merits, against
that framework and what can reasonably be found in it.
[76] This judgment establishes that it would be an error to exclude a
public benefit or detriment on the ground that the Act is
concerned with
efficiency alone. For the avoidance of doubt, it does not follow that the
Commission would err were it to discard
or discount any given public interest
consideration in the circumstances of any given case. There may be good reasons
for doing so.
By way of example only, the case may turn on first-order effects
in relevant markets, or further inquiry may be thought impractical
or
unreasonably costly. More than that we need not say in this case.
[77] The appellants also contend that had Parliament wanted to regulate
plurality in the news media directly it would have enacted
sector-specific
legislation. Mr Goddard submitted that it would be surprising if the Commission
were permitted to act as “the
regulator of everything”, for the role
would take it well outside its statutory framework and institutional competence
and
make the authorisation process much less predictable. Plurality is the
concern not of economic welfare but of social policy. The
Commission may not
fill a perceived gap in media regulation, as it effectively sought to do by
reasoning that existing regulation
in insufficient to protect media plurality
post-transaction.
[78] The High Court rejected these submissions, rightly so in our opinion. The Act manifestly is not designed to regulate the media, but the Commission did not try to do so.102 Its jurisdiction over mergers extends to media businesses, and in this case it engaged with plurality and quality because and to the extent that the transaction would affect those matters.103 It did not assume regulatory oversight of the media by considering whether loss of plurality can safely be left to other regulatory institutions
to address.
1965.
[79] We recognise that the Commission’s internal expertise is
unlikely to extend to media plurality, but we agree with the
High Court that its
processes allow it to obtain expert assistance on the non-market consequences of
a merger.104 That being so, this consideration does not affect our
conclusion that the Commission has jurisdiction to consider
plurality.
[80] We accept that non-economic detriments may complicate merger analysis and introduce an additional element of unpredictability, which is undesirable. We have noted above that fear of uncertainty was a significant consideration when the legislation was enacted. Where the law employs standards, the community looks to courts and tribunals to lend content and predictability when administering it.105
However, this point does not go to jurisdiction either. Some measure of
uncertainty is inherent in the legislative decision to permit
authorisation on
widely-defined public benefit grounds. We reiterate that in adding s 3A to
the Act, Parliament made efficiencies
a mandatory consideration but it did not
exclude others or say anything about the weight to be assigned to
them.
[81] We conclude that the High Court was correct to find that the
Commission might lawfully take into account non-economic or
out of market
detriments when deciding under s 67(3) whether to authorise the
transaction.
Measuring benefits and detriments
[82] We turn to the question whether the High Court erred in applying the
statutory test for identifying and balancing relevant
benefits and
detriments.
“Likely” benefits and detriments
[83] It is settled law that any given benefit or detriment is relevant only if it is likely in the sense that there is a real and substantial risk that it will happen.106
The appellants say that the High Court erred by attaching some weight
to an effect
104 HC judgment, above n 3, at [208]–[210].
105 See the discussion in Richard A Posner Economic Analysis of Law (8th ed, Aspen, New York,
2011) at ch 20.
106 Port Nelson Ltd v Commerce Commission [1996] NZCA 230; [1996] 3 NZLR 554 (CA) at 562–563 [Port Nelson].
that it recognised as unlikely, namely the risk that someone will exploit
ownership of the merged entity for political purposes:107
[275] By comparison with the extent to which major media organisations in
other jurisdictions identify with political parties,
the level of political
influence over media owners in New Zealand is relatively slight. Given that,
and given the initial listed
company ownership structure, we accept the risk of
a dominant ownership position of the merged entity being exploited for political
purposes is somewhat remote. Of course a single ownership structure that creates
even a remote risk of such serious adverse change
is deserving of some
weight.
[84] While the Commission accepts that benefits and detriments must be
likely,
Mr Every-Palmer QC also contended that “likely” is a
“practical filter” rather than a statutory requirement.108
If this latter argument is correct, the Commission would not err if it
counted a remote effect when balancing benefits and detriments
under s 67(3).
This leads us to survey briefly what the authorities have to say on this
point.
[85] To set this discussion in context, we observe that the Commission
makes authorisation decisions under conditions of uncertainty.
The effects
concerned are those judged likely to result in the future from a transaction
that is in prospect. The Commission compares
them with those of a counterfactual
— what will happen in future without the transaction — that need not
be the status
quo. As this Court put it in Commerce Commission v Woolworths
Ltd, both factual and counterfactual are “necessarily incapable of
accurate assessment”.109 As the Court also observed in
Woolworths, it matters who bears the burden of this
uncertainty.110
[86] We derive the following propositions from the
authorities:
(a) An effect is “likely” if there is a “real and substantial risk” or “real chance” that it will occur. It must be more than a mere possibility but need not be more likely than not.111 The likely existence of such a risk
is a practical commercial or economic
question.112 In Woolworths
107 HC judgment, above n 3.
108 The Commission cited AMPS-A (CA), above n 6, at 446 per Richardson J for this, but the word
“practical” occurs there in connection with a different point.
109 Woolworths, above n 68, at [75].
110 At [76].
111 Port Nelson Ltd, above n 106, at 562–563.
112 QCMA, above n 27, at 183; adopted in AMPS-A (HC), above n 69, at 512–513.
the High Court recorded counsels’ agreement that, in general terms, a
real and substantial risk might be one that had at least
a 30 per cent
prospect.113 We mention that not to suggest precision but to
demonstrate that the Commission need not be satisfied that a given effect is
more
likely than any alternative; it must follow that more than one alternative
may qualify for consideration.
(b) The Commission has inquisitorial powers and may
consider information from many sources,114 but it need not continue
its inquiries until it has satisfied itself that the relevant effect is or is
not likely. Rather, it may
rest on the information provided by the
applicant. It must also refuse an authorisation unless satisfied that the
transaction
should be authorised.115 For these reasons the
applicant bears a practical burden of persuasion.116
(c) However, there is no legal burden or evidential standard of
proof.
To say that the Commission is “satisfied” is simply to say that
it has made up its mind on all the material before it.117
(d) What the Commission must be satisfied of is that the acquisition will, or will likely, result in such a benefit to the public that it should be permitted. This is a “balance sheet” exercise, as it was put in QCMA, in which the transaction’s likely benefits are balanced against its likely detriments, the most important detriments normally being those causing
the SLC.118
113 Woolworths Ltd v Commerce Commission [2007] NZHC 1351; (2008) 8 NZBLC 102,128 (HC) at [113]. For the avoidance of doubt, we express no view on the controversial question, which arose in Woolworths, whether this means the Commission must consider multiple counterfactuals where there said to be more than one, or may use the one it thinks more likely.
114 Woolworths, above n 68, at [101]–[102]. The Court there recognised that it is not entirely apt to
speak of “proof”.
115 At [107].
116 At [101]–[102].
117 Z v Dental Complaints Assessment Committee [2008] NZSC 55, [2009] 1 NZLR 1 at [26]
per Elias CJ and [96] per Blanchard, Tipping and McGrath JJ.
118 QCMA, above n 27, at 184.
[87] We take the opportunity to explain what was said about the balancing
exercise in Woolworths. It was common ground between counsel there that
the Commission must ultimately be satisfied on the balance of
probabilities.119 The Court itself used that phrase,120
while recognising that it is inapt insofar as it suggests a standard of
proof. It is inapt because it may suggest that clearance
and authorisation
proceedings are like normal civil proceedings in which a court must decide
causation. For a court causation is
usually a question of historical fact. It
finds the facts on the balance of probabilities, then treats those facts as
certain when
gauging the consequences.121
[88] By contrast, the Commission assesses benefits and detriments that
may be caused in a future state of affairs. Those effects
need not be proved on
the balance of probabilities, and the weight assigned to a given effect may
reflect not only its extent or
impact but also its likelihood. To decide where
the balance lies, then, is to compare one future state of affairs — or an
hypothesis,
to use French J’s term in Australian Gas Light Co v
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission — in which benefits
outweigh detriments with another in which they do not.122 The
Commission may not authorise the transaction unless satisfied that the one state
of affairs is more likely than the other.123
[89] Appeals from the Commission are general in nature, meaning that the appellate court assesses the record against the same standard and forms its own view. An appellant bears the burden of satisfying the court that the decision below was wrong, but if the court reaches a different conclusion on the merits then the Commission, or the intermediate appellate court as the case may be, was wrong “in the only sense that matters”.124 There is room for deference to the Commission’s
or High Court’s advantages of process or expertise.125
We record that we do not defer
119 Woolworths, above n 68, at [97].
120 At [102].
121 See for example Allied Maples Group Ltd v Simmons & Simmons [1995] EWCA Civ 17; [1995] 1 WLR 1602 (CA) at
1609–1610 per Stuart-Smith LJ. Of course the court may assess damages on a lost chance basis if loss depends on a future event the happening of which is contingent on someone else’s actions.
122 Australian Gas Light Co v Australian Competition and Consumer Commission [2003] FCA
1525[2003] FCA 1525; , (2003) 137 FCR 317 at [356].
123 John Land and Leela Cejnar “Counterfactual Analysis in Merger Reviews” (2012) 25 NZULR
103 at 115.
124 Austin, Nichols & Co Inc v Stichting Lodestar [2007] NZSC 103, [2008] 2 NZLR 141 at [16].
125 Woolworths, above n 68, at [57]–[61].
in this appeal, which turns on questions that we find ourselves able to
answer on the material before us.
The ‘single owner risk’
[90] We turn to the appellants’ argument that the High Court erred
by taking into account a risk that is less than likely,
namely the risk that
someone will exploit ownership of the merged entity for political
purposes.
[91] We have set out the Court’s conclusion above. It
characterised the risk as “somewhat remote” but deserving
of
“some weight” because the effect would be serious if it came to
pass. Mr Every-Palmer argued that by using this
language the Court was merely
locating the risk at the lower end of a spectrum of likely effects. (We observe
that the Commission
itself did not characterise the risk in that way in its
determination, stating rather that there is little to prevent a change in
shareholding.126) Counsel pointed out that the Court concluded that
“the importance of the likely loss of plurality” and prospect of
reduced
quality outweighed the transaction’s benefits, so characterising
loss of plurality as likely.127 He emphasised, citing Godfrey
Hirst (No 2), that it is “false scientism” to insist on an
express calculation of probabilities.128
[92] In our opinion the High Court erred to the extent that it took into account what it considered a remote risk that a single owner would exploit the merged entity for political purposes. We agree that even a remote risk of this kind is a matter of public concern. Post-transaction, NZME’s substantial presence in relevant markets would create a vulnerability that ought to worry policymakers. But unless the risk is thought “likely” it should not enter the balance under s 67(3). Before us, the Commission did not suggest that it is likely. NZME, which is to be the acquirer, is listed on the NZX and we were given to understand that it is widely held. A subsidiary of Fairfax Media Ltd, which is listed on the ASX, would own 41 per cent of NZME’s shares following the transaction. This we take to be a controlling interest in the merged entity.
But Fairfax Media also appears to be widely held. So it seems that
absent a substantial
126 CC determination, above n 1, at [1625].
127 HC judgment, above n 3, at [306].
128 Godfrey Hirst (No 2), above n 92, at [37].
change in shareholding no one person would be in a position to impose their
own political agenda on NZME.
[93] We do accept that the error has no practical significance.
Because the possibility was remote it was evidently
assigned little weight, as
one would expect. The balancing exercise turned primarily on quality, not
plurality, and the Court’s
decision was not finely balanced. We also note
that the Commission did not make the same error.
[94] Further, it does not follow that loss of plurality ought to have
been discounted, nor adverse effects on democracy. We return
to the
significance of plurality below at [121].
Objective, transparent and rigorous reasoning required
[95] The appellants cite Richardson J’s judgment in
AMPS-A (CA) for the proposition that analysis must be transparent,
structured and rigorous.129 They accept that not all benefits and
detriments can be quantified, but argue that the High Court erred by concluding
that because
loss of plurality is unquantifiable it might rely on intuitive
judgement.130 The Commission and the Court ought to have employed
an analytical technique such as break-even analysis, which would require that
they estimate the costs of remedying the losses of plurality and quality and
measure those costs against the transaction’s
benefits.131
The cost of remedy would be measured by estimating the cost of journalist
and editorial staff needed to replace those lost to the
transaction. Had that
been done, it would have been apparent that the transaction would yield a clear
net public benefit.
[96] In AMPS-A (CA) Richardson J spoke, in a well-known passage,
of:132
...the desirability of quantifying benefits and detriments where and to the
extent that it is feasible to do so. The commission encourages
applicants to
quantify anticipated public benefits. In this case certain major efficiency
gains were quantified for Telecom at some
$75 million. While both the
commission
129 AMPS-A (CA), above n 6, at 447.
130 HC judgment, above n 3, at [80] and [299].
131 Cass R Sunstein Simpler: The Future of Government (Simon & Schuster, New York, 2014)
at 171–172.
132 AMPS-A (CA), above n 6, at 447.
and the Court did not accept elements in that quantification, both bodies
considered that there would be significant efficiency gains
if Telecom had
management rights over both AMPS-A and AMPS-B. In those circumstances there is
in my view a responsibility on a regulatory
body to attempt so far as possible
to quantify detriments and benefits rather than rely on a purely intuitive
judgment to justify
a conclusion that detriments in fact exceed quantified
benefits.
[97] In that case, as we have already noted, wider public benefit
considerations were not in issue. The benefits and detriments
were almost all
efficiency gains and losses, and it was these that Richardson J said should be
quantified so far as possible. Speaking
more generally, Richardson J cautioned
against speculation and intuition, urging that “the value judgment should
be as informed
by practical evidence as
possible”.133
[98] We accept Mr Goddard’s submission that Richardson J’s underlying point, which we affirm, was that the Commission’s reasoning ought to be as objective, rigorous and transparent as feasible. The Act uses economic concepts — markets, market power, substantial lessening of competition — that permit informed evaluation.134 We accept that the Commission ought to measure gains and losses where it is sufficiently feasible and instructive to do so, and otherwise ought to ensure that the value judgement required of it is informed by practical evidence and analysis. If it fails to meet this standard then it risks reversal on the merits on appeal. But quantification can convey an impression of precision that is quite misleading.135
We caution too that while efficiency considerations may predominate in
merger
analysis, and some efficiencies are measurable, it is an error to reason that the authorisation process is concerned only with, or values most, those things that can be measured. If made, that error would introduce a bias in favour of measurable efficiency considerations that, as we have explained, is not found in the statutory
authorisation standard
itself.136
133 At 446.
134 At 441–442.
135 Godfrey Hirst (No 2), above n 92, at [37].
136 At [35]–[38]. Compare Michael S Jacobs “An Essay on the Normative Foundations of Antitrust
Economics” (1995) 74 N C L Rev 219 at 230–231.
Adequacy of the Commission’s methodology
[99] For the most part, the appellants do not challenge the methodology
adopted by the Commission and the High Court. It produced,
as already noted,
substantial estimated efficiency gains. They focus rather on the treatment of
plurality and quality detriments.
[100] The appellants first argued that plurality ought to have been
unbundled so that each of its elements was separately analysed,
for two reasons:
plurality has two dimensions (voice and political influence) that are not
equally likely to suffer in the factual,
and the Commission’s analysis of
plurality was so abstract as to be meaningless. Next, it was said that the
Commission and
the High Court failed to identify the nature and extent of
plurality detriments, as they must do in order to assign weight to them.
Finally, it was said that the High Court erred by taking an intuitive approach
to the balancing exercise, for even unquantifiable
benefits may be subjected to
cost-benefit analysis. Mr Goddard instanced break-even analysis, under which
judgment is informed
by closely analysing the nature and extent of the
unquantifiable effect.137 He also argued that the detriment may be
measured by its costs of avoidance; in this case, the cost of journalists and
editorial staff
positions lost in the transaction, and that cost is very much
less than the efficiency gains.
[101] We preface what we have to say by observing that while some
methodological practices, such as the use of counterfactuals,
have become
settled over time, the Act itself does not prescribe a methodology for
identifying and evaluating benefits and detriments,
including the SLC. It
leaves the Commission to choose a methodology that seems best suited to the
circumstances. In ACCC the Full Federal Court for this reason rejected
an argument that the Tribunal must assign explicit and lesser weightings
to public benefits that are not dispersed among
consumers.138
[102] The argument that the dimensions of plurality ought to have been unbundled derived much of its force from the proposition that the High Court erred by giving weight to the single owner risk. We have held, however, that the error was of little
practical significance. The Commission’s further response is that
plurality is not susceptible to unbundling and it did what
it could to gauge
extent and weight; it used hard data where possible and consulted widely and
employed the Ofcom measures mentioned
above. We agree. The dimensions of
plurality overlap. Our attention has not been drawn to a methodology that might
allow them
to be separated and separately measured.
[103] In AMPS-A (CA) Richardson J said that decisions should not be
made in a “purely intuitive” way.139 It does not follow
that the High Court erred when it stated, after noting the absence of any
quantitative evidence of “the impact
of a reduction in quality causing a
reduction in the number of visits to an appellant’s online site”,
that the competing
views on quality were “therefore
intuitive”.140 The statement was made when addressing an
argument that the appellants’ need for advertising would constrain their
capacity
to reduce quality in news. The Court surveyed the practical evidence
about that before concluding that an intuitive judgment was
required. It did
not say that in the absence of quantitative evidence all judgments are
intuitive, or that its decision need not
be informed by the evidence. The
question before it turned on an effect — reduction in news consumption in
response to a loss
of quality — that is incapable of measurement and we
think the Court was saying no more than that.
[104] Mr Goddard did not argue that the Commission must employ break-even
analysis, using the technique rather to illustrate that
unquantifiable
detriments can be assessed in a rigorous way. We take the point so far as it
goes. But it has not been shown that
any alternative methodology would make any
difference here. We consider that the Commission’s process was
sufficiently
disciplined and its conclusions generally robust.
[105] We turn lastly to the argument that the costs of avoiding harm to plurality and quality are the proper measure of these detriments. The appellants say that if it would cost less than $130 to $200 million to avoid these detriments then the harm they cause cannot sensibly be ascribed a higher value. Mr Goddard submitted that the High Court
misunderstood this argument when it responded that the benefits do not
represent a sum available to New Zealand to avoid the
detriments.141
[106] We do not accept that plurality and quality detriments can be
measured by the cost of employing journalists and editors to
replace those whose
positions are lost in the merged firm. The harm caused may be much greater
than that. If it can be remedied
at a cost which is by comparison modest, then
the question naturally arises whether anyone would supply the funding in order
to avert
the harm. There being no realistic possibility of new entry, the
funding would have to come from the public purse. The Commission
and the High
Court did not find that a sufficiently real possibility, and as the High
Court pointed out in the passage
just mentioned, the appellants were not
offering to share their private efficiency gains to that end. We do not suggest
that they
ought to do so. But neither do we agree that the High Court missed
the point.
Were the Commission and the High Court wrong on the
merits?
[107] We introduce this section by remarking on the factual and
counterfactual. Printed newspapers are following a declining trajectory
that the
transaction might slow for a time but could not arrest. The appellants hope
that the transaction will provide “additional
runway” for adaptation
over the next five years. So there is a substantial degree of uncertainty about
what Mr Goddard called
the delta, the difference between factual and
counterfactual, and that must affect the accuracy of any assessment of benefits
and
detriments.
[108] The appellants rely on the delta’s uncertainty to challenge the Commission’s and the High Court’s assessments of plurality and quality detriments. Mr Goddard emphasised that they did not gauge how much of these effects would be felt within the next five years. However, the point cuts both ways, lending force to the Commission’s argument that the appellants are wrong to treat the efficiency gains as “bankable”. The gains were not detailed in a merger implementation plan. Rather, they were derived from a PriceWaterhouseCoopers report which it seems the appellants
themselves described during the Commission’s investigation
as an “academic
141 At [300].
exercise”. The Commission took advice from an accounting firm, BDO, but
it did not audit the estimates. Rather, it worked with
them, typically stating
that it accepted the ranges offered by PwC as “reasonable
estimates”.142 We take the same approach.
Quality detriments
[109] We turn to one benefit, a productive efficiency gain through savings
in editorial staff numbers, which came to the forefront
in argument. It did so
because counsel treated journalists’ time, and hence journalist numbers,
as a rough proxy for quality
in news.
[110] The appellants say, relying on the PwC report, that the transaction
would result in the firm shedding some 13 per cent, of
their editorial staff, in
which we include journalists. This is seemingly a modest percentage. Mr
Goddard argued that it is so
because journalists generate the content that
allows the appellants to sell attention and so drives revenue from both
advertising
and subscriptions.
[111] In argument before us, the Commission pointed out that the 13 per
cent figure excludes some editorial staff counted by PwC,
that the PwC report
suggested the merged entity might shed a materially higher percentage,
15–20 per cent, and that even this
figure is under-inclusive because some
editorial staff were categorised differently.
[112] In its determination the Commission made a further point about the
PwC estimates, noting that for confidentiality reasons
PwC had not been able to
share their thinking with NZME and Fairfax management. It illustrated the
resulting reliability concern
by noting that the report adopted the dubious
assumption that general news reporters would be rationalised only where the
parties
overlap geographically.143
[113] The appellants respond by identifying a number of structural and behavioural factors that offset their incentive to reduce costs by shedding editorial staff.
They contend that any losses would be confined to coverage of arcane
topics and a
modest
reduction in the number of perspectives offered on topics of secondary public
interest. Among other points:
(a) Audience attention is their only source of revenue in both
subscription and advertising markets. They maximise it by using
their editorial
staff to supply diverse views and quality journalism, so appealing to readers
who have diverse interests and many
competing claims on their attention, and in
that way they maximise revenue from both advertisers (the only source of revenue
on “free”
digital media such as Stuff) and subscribers.
(b) There is evidence, which the Commission accepted, that consumers
respond to changes in perceived quality.144
(c) The appellants experience competition from other media, such
as free-to-air television and radio, as well as news
aggregators such as
Facebook. Competition for attention is not confined to content generated by
journalists; it includes reader-generated
content.
(d) Policy interventions, such as increased public funding for Radio
New
Zealand, provide (or could provide) external constraints.
(e) Editors adhere to codes of conduct and ethics, and the appellants
are regulated by the Media Council.
[114] These arguments did not carry the day below. The Commission’s
detailed reasoning is dispersed through sections covering
effects in differing
markets and scenarios, and some of it is combined with discussion of plurality,
but these passages fairly summarise
its conclusions:
887. In response to a reduction in competition and, therefore, less competitive pressure to attract audiences, we consider that the merged entity would be likely to have less incentive to invest in editorial resources. We consider that this would be likely to include not only the number of journalists hired, but that the merged entity could also reduce the amount it invests in journalism and/or invests in journalist training. Such decisions may
not affect the volume and variety of stories produced, but could reduce the
quality of the article, for example, a journalist may
be given less training or
less resources for in-depth analysis, such as travel expenses.
...
894. We consider that the reductions of editorial staff are likely to
have a significant effect on the quality of online New Zealand
news that would
be produced with the merger. We are of the view that NZME and Fairfax
currently compete to invest in and deploy
their editorial resources in a manner
which they consider will best attract readers of online New Zealand news. This
involves editors
allocating resources to produce news that is varied in terms of
the topics that are covered and the perspectives and viewpoints
discussed.
...
897. Given these different perspectives, we consider that a
rationalisation of editorial roles due to a reduction of competition
is likely
to result in a degradation of quality of news produced by the merged entity, as
there would be a reduction in the variety
of editorial decision-making. In
particular, there is likely to be a concentration of editorial opinions around
what topics to cover
and what stance, angle or perspective to write on
particular issues and what stories are given prominence.
[115] The High Court found that:145
[76] ... We consider it an inevitable part of the rationale for the
merger that efficiencies pursued would include scaling back
journalistic and
editorial resources, as well as managerial resources. One necessary consequence
of doing so would be a reduction
in quality. We are therefore satisfied that
there would be a material reduction in the scope of topics reported upon, and
the diversity
of views expressed within them. That would constitute a reduction
in quality.
[77] We do not consider it a sufficient answer that the merged business
would be economically incentivised to provide coverage
on what readers want.
Dissatisfaction with a reduction in the scope of what is published is unlikely
to be conveyed either promptly
or effectively enough to influence management
decisions on what may appear to be duplicated resources, but which readers would
prefer
were retained. So too with the level of more arcane topics that are
likely not to be covered post-merger. We agree with the Commission
that the
merged entity could reduce the quality of its output in numerous respects that
would not be observed by consumers in any
concerted way, so that the reduction
in quality could be effected without producing any compelling demand for
restoration of the
qualities that existed in the competitive era.
[78] We also agree with the Commission that competition between news
producers stimulates coverage by each of a wider range of
topics than would be
covered in a non-competitive environment. If one publication covers
a
145 HC judgment, above n 3.
news story, then its rival will be incentivised to cover that story as well,
albeit with a different perspective.
[79] We are mindful that senior editorial staff currently employed by
the appellants provided assurances of their intentions
to maintain variety and
diversity of news content. We have no reason to doubt the integrity of the
editorial personnel and respect
their commitment. The commercial reality is
that the extent to which they can achieve variety and diversity of news content
will
be dictated by management decisions.
[116] We share these views. In our opinion, in the factual the merged
entity will have a powerful incentive to save costs by shedding
journalists and
editorial staff, with a corresponding impact on quality. The incentive is
powerful because the firm will be under
pressure to extend the
“runway” so far as it can. We think that reductions would likely
exceed those estimated by the
appellants in argument before us, with a
correspondingly substantial effect on quality. It is difficult to gauge, but we
think that
staff reductions at the upper end of the PwC range would cause
quality effects of a substantial magnitude. We recognise that larger
reductions would also increase efficiency gains.
[117] By way of explanation, we accept that the merged firm will continue
to experience incentives to supply quality journalism.
But we make four
points:
(a) We agree with the Commission and the High Court, for the reasons
they gave, that competition between the appellants is a
major driver of quality
at present. The Commission found that each of the appellants considers the
other its major rival.146 One witness described how they monitor
and mimic one another’s behaviour. We discuss below an example, the
conduct of NZME
when considering whether to establish a paywall. The transaction
would eliminate all of that.
(b) Competition from other media would not replace that leading
incentive.
Such would be the merged firm’s share of news content generated and consumed in newspaper and online markets that competitive pressure
would be attenuated.147 Other competitors also
use distribution
146 CC determination, above n 1, at [706].
platforms, notably free to air television and radio,
that are not yet full substitutes for the appellants’ newspapers, and some
of them do not enjoy the trust that the appellants have established
among consumers.148
(c) The appellants’ incentive is to maximise profit, not gross
revenue.
The incentive to cut costs as the firm sought to extend the
“runway”
would operate until revenue losses began to outweigh the costs
saved.
(d) Consumers do respond to perceived quality losses by reducing
consumption, but the emphasis is on “perceived”.
We agree with the
Commission and the High Court that consumers do not find it easy to gauge
quality and may adapt to quality changes
without noticing
them.149
[118] We accept that increased funding for public media is likely. We were
supplied with evidence of a Budget commitment to increase
funding by $15 million
to increase media contribution to an informed democracy, through the
establishment of a Ministerial Advisory
Group. We reject the
Commission’s submission that it is speculative for us to have regard
to those commitments, but
we do nonetheless accept that publicly-owned media
organisations (or policy intervention more generally) are unlikely to address
our concerns about loss of quality. Existing public media organisations do not
operate in most of the relevant markets. Consistent
with that, the Chief
Executive and Editor in Chief of Radio New Zealand, Mr Paul Thompson, explained
that (in his view) Radio New
Zealand was “never a direct competitor”
to the appellants, and saw its relationship with the appellants as a more
collaborative
one.
[119] We accept, as did the High Court, that editors adhere to codes of conduct and ethics, but we share its view, and that of the Commission, that neither this nor Press Council decision-making can protect against quality reductions. The point is well explained by Dr Peter Thompson, a senior lecturer in media studies at
Victoria University:
148 At [240]–[242], [536], [591], [596], [1555] and [1563].
149 CC determination, above n 1, at [733]; and HC judgment, above n 3, at [288].
[T]he competitive pressure to get that story first but also to get that story
right is I think very important. And if there’s
a hollowing out of the
news budget, I mean it’s all very well the editors saying “Oh
we’ve got integrity, we protect
our independence”, that may not be
[the] budget choice for them to make. And they don’t know, they
can’t possibly
say what the future will hold under the new company
structure...
[120] It follows that in our opinion the transaction would be very likely
to result in quality reductions and these would likely
be of a substantial
nature.
Plurality
[121] When assessing the transaction’s effect on plurality care must
be taken to not double-count quality effects that have
already been recognised
when predicting how the merged firm would behave in the factual. Plurality
effects will be felt generally
throughout the community.
[122] Plurality matters in this case because the transaction would affect
it in a substantial way. New Zealand markets are already
highly concentrated
by international standards and the appellants account for a very large
share of the production and
distribution of news. The transaction would reduce
to four the number of major news providers, and the merged entity would employ
many more journalists and editorial staff than Television New Zealand,
Mediaworks and Radio New Zealand combined.150 It would account for
almost 90 per cent of daily newspaper circulation (with an extensive regional
presence), control the two largest
New Zealand online news suppliers and the two
major Sunday papers, and through NZME’s stable of nine radio stations
account
for a substantial share of the radio market.
[123] We accepted at [92] above that the High Court was wrong to take into account the risk of a single owner exploiting the merged entity for political purposes. However, as Mr Every-Palmer submitted, concentrated ownership is not a prerequisite to a media organisation setting an editorial agenda or campaigning for a cause. Even if its owners are politically agnostic, the merged firm is more likely to follow a uniform
approach in its various publications. We agree with the High
Court that the
150 The data are confidential: [
].
competition provided under the factual is a better way of securing a
diversity of views than the discretionary internal plurality
that would exist in
the merged entity.151
[124] Diversity of views is also intrinsically valuable.152 To
cite John Stuart Mill:153
Why is it, then, that there is on the whole a preponderance among mankind of
rational opinions and rational conduct? ... it is owing
to a quality of the
human mind, the source of everything respectable in man either as an
intellectual or as a moral being, namely
that his errors are corrigible. He is
capable of rectifying his mistakes, by discussion and experience. Not by
experience alone.
There must be discussion, to show how experience is to be
interpreted. Wrong opinions and practices gradually yield to fact and argument;
but facts and arguments, to produce any effect on the mind, must be brought
before it.
[125] This “marketplace of ideas” justification recognises that the community benefits from a variety of different perspectives and from allowing people to participate in the community by expressing those views.154 There were a significant number of submitters to the Commission, both with backgrounds in journalism and from the wider community, who emphasised the importance of a diversity of views to the functioning of the media and society. The point is well explained by
Mr Richard Sutherland of Mediaworks:
I think probably the best way to describe it is that the mainstream media
outlets in this country kind of operate ... a broader news
ecosystem and we sort
of, feed and prompt each other into covering stories, you know if there was only
one of us there’d be
a ... lot fewer stories being generated ... you know
diversity would probably fall away simply because there’s not as many
people out there making calls, banging doors, you know checking that sort of
thing.
[126] Our findings on quality apply to plurality. We have rejected the appellants’ arguments that there will be only minor reductions in editorial staff and that any losses will be offset by other media. We find it very likely that there will be a substantial
loss of plurality in the factual that will not be experienced in the
counterfactual.
151 HC judgment, above n 3, at [276].
153 John Stuart Mill On Liberty (first published 1859; republished Batoche Books, Ontario, 2001)
at 21.
154 Attorney-General v Times Newspapers Ltd [1974] AC 273 (HL) at 315 per Lord Simon.
The paywall issue
[127] Our decision does not turn on this issue. However, we have formed a
view on
it.
[128] By way of introduction, the Commission attributed several specific
losses of allocative efficiency to the transaction. These
it quantified and
deducted from quantified efficiency gains. The losses would arise in the
community newspaper advertising and
Sunday newspaper advertising markets, from
increases in the cover and subscription price for Sunday newspapers and from the
implementation
of a paywall for online news.155 The High Court
found that a paywall is not likely following the transaction and the
Commission contends that it was wrong.156 On this issue turns
between $0 and $[12–16] million in efficiency losses per year and a minor
consequential change in the value
assigned to wealth transfers from consumers to
non-New Zealand shareholders in the merged entity.157
[129] The Commission contends that a paywall is likely, highlighting
a recent announcement by NZME that it intends to launch
a paywall for
“premium content” on its website for online news, nzherald.co.nz.
It also highlights a report from Fairfax
that paid digital subscriptions for
three of its Australian media, The Sydney Morning Herald, The Age
and The Australian Financial Review, have increased in number for
four consecutive years.
[130] Competition between the appellants is presently a major impediment to a paywall, as the High Court recognised.158 The evidence before the Commission was
that [
155 CC determination, above n 1, at [1239], [1244]–[1246] and [1266]–[1268].
156 HC judgment, above n 3, at [123].
1262[2016] NZHC 1262; , [2016] 3 NZLR 645 at [39]. We do not consider it necessary for us to re-examine the wealth transfers issue in this Court.
158 HC judgment, above n 3, at [121].
].159 The Court nonetheless found a general paywall unlikely,
because the loss of advertising revenue would exceed
subscriptions.160
[131] We prefer the view that some form of paywall, most likely a
restrictive content paywall like that recently announced by NZME,
would be
implemented by the merged entity. The Commission emphasises confidential
information provided by NZME that detailed a possible
subscription model it
could implement. [
].161 Assuming the merged entity employed a similar model and
priced subscriptions to offset the loss of advertising revenues just detailed,
a
restricted-content paywall is a commercially feasible option for the merged
entity, and there is a real chance one could be implemented
following the
transaction given the significant reduction in competitive pressure that flows
from the merged entity controlling both
nzherald.co.nz and
stuff.co.nz.
[132] Accordingly, we reinstate the Commission’s findings on
quantified detriments as they relate to the paywall. This means
that the
quantified net benefits attributable to the transaction is approximately
$[65–75] million to $200 million.
The balancing exercise
[133] We may state our conclusions shortly. We accept the range of likely
quantified efficiency flowing from the transaction, while
noting that they are
mere estimates the reliability of which is difficult to assess and recording
that the range is somewhat reduced
by reinstatement of the paywall.
[134] We consider that quality and plurality detriments are very likely to result from the transaction. We have examined quality effects first because we consider them more immediate and find them easier to gauge. Counsel used journalist and editorial
staff numbers as a proxy for quality, as noted. We consider that the
transaction will
159 CC determination, above n 1, at [788]–[791].
160 HC judgment, above n 3, at [123].
announcement it intends to implement a public paywall now.
cause a substantial reduction in numbers. We agree with the High Court that
quality detriments are very likely and substantial. We
consider that they are
sufficient in themselves to outweigh the transaction’s
benefits.
[135] Additional plurality losses are also very likely and substantial. We
agree with the High Court and the Commission that plurality
is a characteristic
of media markets that is vitally important to the community. We also agree with
the High Court that the loss
of plurality attributable to the transaction would
very likely be irreparable.
[136] These conclusions flow from the appellants’ powerful position
in New Zealand markets that are already highly concentrated,
the attenuation of
competitive pressure to maintain quality of journalism post-transaction, and the
incentives that the merged firm
would experience to cut costs.
[137] In the result, we find that detriments clearly outweigh benefits, and
not by a small margin. It follows that authorisation
was properly declined
below.
Result
[138] As noted, this is a general appeal, not confined to the questions
that the High Court identified when granting leave. It
is nonetheless
appropriate to answer those questions:
a) Was the High Court correct, as a matter of law, to find that the
Commission had jurisdiction to take into account non-economic,
unquantified
detriments (in the form of plurality losses) when applying the legal test for
authorisation under s 67(3) of the Commerce
Act 1986?
Yes.
b) Did the High Court err in law and fact when applying the statutory test of whether the unquantified detriments and plurality detriments identified by the NZCC were “likely”, and were attributable to the transaction?
The High Court erred to the extent that it assigned weight to a risk that it
considered remote, namely the risk that a single owner
would exploit the merged
entity for political purposes. It did not otherwise err.
c) Did the High Court err in fact and law in its approach to
balancing unquantifiable detriments against the net qualified
benefits of the
transaction?
No.
[139] The third of these answers disposes of the appeal on the merits. The
appeal is accordingly dismissed.
[140] The appellants are jointly and severally liable to pay the respondent
costs for a complex appeal on a band B basis and usual
disbursements. We
certify for second counsel.
Solicitors:
Russell McVeagh, Auckland for Appellants
Meredith Connell, Wellington for Respondents
Solicitors:
NZLII:
Copyright Policy
|
Disclaimers
|
Privacy Policy
|
Feedback
URL: http://www.nzlii.org/nz/cases/NZCA/2018/389.html