Home
| Databases
| WorldLII
| Search
| Feedback
High Court of New Zealand Decisions |
Last Updated: 1 February 2018
For a Court ready (fee required) version please follow this link
IN THE HIGH COURT OF NEW ZEALAND AUCKLAND REGISTRY
CIV-2015-404-002719 [2016] NZHC 1262
UNDER
|
the Commerce Act 1986
|
BETWEEN
|
GODFREY HIRST NZ LIMITED Appellant
|
AND
|
COMMERCE COMMISSION First Respondent
CAVALIER WOOL HOLDINGS LIMITED
Second Respondent
NEW ZEALAND WOOL SERVICES INTERNATIONAL LIMITED
Third Respondent
|
Hearing:
|
4 - 8 April 2016
|
Court:
|
Gilbert J
Professor Martin Richardson, Lay Member
|
Counsel:
|
J C L Dixon and S D J Peart for Appellant
M Dunning QC, N F Flanagan and E Rutherford for First
Respondent
D J Goddard QC, S J P Ladd and J Q Wilson for Second and
Third Respondents
|
Judgment:
|
13 June 2016
|
JUDGMENT OF GILBERT J
This judgment is delivered by me on 13 June 2016 at 3 pm pursuant to r 11.5 of the High Court Rules.
Registrar / Deputy Registrar
Solicitors:
Chapman Tripp, Wellington
Merediths, Auckland
Counsel:
J C L Dixon, Auckland
D J Goddard QC, Wellington
M Dunning QC, Auckland
GODFREY HIRST NZ LTD v COMMERCE COMMISSION & Ors [2016] NZHC 1262 [13 June 2016]
Contents
Introduction
..........................................................................................................[1]
Approach on appeal
.............................................................................................[9]
Should the Commission have disregarded the benefits that will flow offshore to Lempriere?
The Commission’s approach ......................................................................[10]
Submissions................................................................................................[14]
Analysis
......................................................................................................[20]
Did the Commission underestimate the likely price increases?
.....................[41]
Should the Commission have disregarded the benefits from
closing Kaputone?
..............................................................................................[57]
Did the Commission overestimate the likely redundancy costs
at
Kaputone?.......................................................................................................[67]
Was the Commission correct to disregard the benefits of closing Clive?
.....[68]
Result ...................................................................................................................[74]
Introduction
[1] Godfrey Hirst appeals against the Commerce Commission’s
determination dated 12 November 2015 granting Cavalier
Wool Holdings
Ltd (Cavalier) authorisation pursuant to s 67(3)(b) of the Commerce Act 1986
to acquire control over the wool
scouring business and assets of New
Zealand Wool Services International Ltd (NZWSI).1 Cavalier and
NZWSI are the only providers of wool scouring services in New Zealand so the
proposed acquisition will create a domestic
monopoly for such
services.
[2] The acquisition will enable the rationalisation of the Cavalier and
NZWSI scouring operations from five to two, one
in the North Island
and one in the South Island. NZWSI’s South Island scour lines
situated at Kaputone
near Christchurch will be relocated to Cavalier’s
South Island operation at Timaru. Similarly, NZWSI’s North Island
scour lines at Whakatu, Hawkes Bay, will be relocated to Cavalier’s
facilities at Awatoto, also in Hawkes Bay. The
merging parties will then sell
the Kaputone and Whakatu properties and any surplus plant. Cavalier will
decommission its scour
line at Clive, Hawkes Bay, and sell the
property.
[3] Godfrey Hirst is affected because, as a manufacturer of woollen carpets in New Zealand, it purchases scoured wool. The Commission considered that the acquisition would be likely to result in scouring price increases of between five and
25 per cent for Godfrey Hirst and between five and 15 per cent for wool destined for export. The Commission nevertheless considered that the benefits of the transaction were likely to exceed its detriments. It assessed the net present value of the likely net benefit over a five year period as being between $1.15 million and
$23.48 million. Over a 10 year period, the Commission assessed the net present value of the likely net public benefit as ranging between negative $0.82 million and
positive $34.33 million.
[4] Godfrey Hirst appeals
against the determination arguing that the Commission made three significant
errors, any one of which
it contends is sufficient to require that the
authorisation be overturned:
(a) The Commission ought to have discounted the benefits of
the acquisition that will accrue to the foreign shareholder
of the merged
entity, Lempriere (Australia) Pty Ltd. Forty five per cent of the
merged entity will be owned by Lempriere
and it will have an option to increase
its shareholding to 72.5 per cent. Godfrey Hirst argues that the benefits that
will flow
to Lempriere from the acquisition are not benefits to the public in
New Zealand and should have been disregarded.
(b) The Commission underestimated the likely price increases for
scouring services for wool destined for export following
the acquisition.
Godfrey Hirst argues that the likely price increases will be in the range of 10
to 20 per cent, not five to 15
per cent as assessed by the
Commission.
(c) The Commission overestimated the benefits because it is likely that
NZWSI will relocate the Kaputone scour to Timaru whether
or not the acquisition
goes ahead.
[5] Cavalier argues that the case for authorisation is
stronger than the
Commission assessed and it supports the determination on the following
grounds:
(a) The Commission overestimated the likely redundancy costs payable to
employees on closure of the Kaputone plant.
(b) The Commission ought to have taken into account the closure of the Clive plant as a benefit of the transaction because there is a real chance that it will not close if the acquisition does not proceed.
[6] The parties disagree about the correct test to be applied to an application for authorisation under s 67. Godfrey Hirst contends that an authorisation can only be granted where the Commission is able to exclude the real chance that there will be no net public benefit. The Commission’s analysis identified the prospect of a net public detriment over a 10 year period although it considered that there was “only a remote possibility that the values would align in such a way that, over the 10-year timeframe, the extremities near the lower bounds and upper bounds would be
realised”.2 Godfrey Hirst accepts that if this analysis
is correct, then authorisation
could properly have been granted. However, Godfrey Hirst argues that if any
one of its grounds of appeal succeeds, it will not be
possible to exclude the
real chance of a net public detriment and the authorisation could not
stand.
[7] Cavalier and the Commission dispute this analysis. They argue that
an authorisation can properly be granted even if there
is a real chance that
there will be a net detriment so long as the risk of this occurring is
sufficiently outweighed by the likely
benefit.
[8] The contest over the correct approach to an authorisation under s
67 will only need to be determined if one or more of the
other grounds of appeal
succeeds. We therefore consider the other grounds first.
Approach on appeal
[9] An appeal from a determination of the Commerce Commission under s 67 is by way of a re-hearing. The approach is as directed by the Supreme Court in Austin, Nichols & Co Inc v Stichting Lodestar.3 The appellant has the onus of satisfying the Court that it should differ from the decision appealed from. The Court will not interfere unless it is persuaded that the decision is wrong. The Court must make its own assessment of the merits of the case even where this requires an assessment of fact and degree and involves a value judgment upon which reasonable minds may differ. The weight that should be attached to the Commission’s conclusion on any
particular issue is a matter for the Court’s judgment. We bear in
mind that the
Commission is a specialist body with broad investigative powers and it
undertook a
2 Final determination, at [633].
3 Austin, Nichols & Co Inc v Stichting Lodestar [2007] NZSC 103, [2008] 2 NZLR 141.
comprehensive investigation extending over a 12 month period. The Commission conducted numerous interviews with industry participants, obtained expert assistance, issued two draft determinations and considered submissions from interested parties before issuing its final determination. The Court may rightly hesitate before concluding that findings of fact and degree are wrong. Nevertheless, as Cooke P stated in Telecom Corporation of New Zealand v Commerce Commission “there can be no suggestion of rubber-stamping a decision simply because it
represents the views of experts”.4
Should the Commission have disregarded the benefits that will flow offshore to
Lempriere?
The Commission’s approach
[10] The Commission noted that the primary benefits of the acquisition will come from the rationalisation of the scouring operations from five sites to two. This will improve economies of scale and generate cost savings and will enable the Whakatu and Kaputone sites to be released for other uses.5 The Commission found that the benefits from these productive efficiency gains will flow to the shareholders.6 Given that 45 per cent of these benefits will go offshore to Lempriere (leaving aside its
option to increase its shareholding following the acquisition), the
Commission concluded that this proportion does not directly benefit
the New
Zealand public:
[400] Consequently, as the benefits from these productive efficiency gains
will flow to foreign shareholders, these are not direct
public benefits to New
Zealand.
[11] However, the Commission relied on this Court’s decision in
Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce Commission
(AMPS-A) in concluding that these gains to foreign shareholders
should not be discounted:7
[401] However, while focusing on shareholder residency may provide an
accurate estimate of the immediate, direct benefits
that arise within
the market of interest, it is the Commission’s view, following
the Court’s
4 Telecom Corporation of New Zealand v Commerce Commission [1992] 3 NZLR 429 (CA)
at 434.
5 Final determination, at [388].
6 At [395].
7 Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce Commission (1991) 4 TCLR 473 (HC).
decision in AMPS-A, that this approach ignores other longer-term or wider
public benefits.
[12] The Commission considered there were two offsetting
“feedback” benefits
such that the productive efficiency benefits should be recognised in their
entirety:
[404] The Commission considers that the productivity enhancements that
would be obtained by [Cavalier] in terms of asset realisations
and cost
reductions should be included in the assessment of public benefits. This is
despite the fact that some proportion of these
gains would flow directly to
foreign shareholders in the first instance. This approach, consistent with
case law, recognises that
enabling foreign shareholders to undertake such cost
minimisation can provide significant flow-on benefits to New Zealand.
[405] There are two main flow-on (feedback) benefits that are relevant in
this case.
[406] The first is that real cost savings brought about by the merger
could ultimately enable the merged firm to better compete
against international
rivals. This may improve the likelihood that the domestic scouring sector would
continue to operate profitably
over the longer term. This could
produce greater public benefits to New Zealand than may otherwise be the case if
denying
the merger would prevent the sector from undertaking beneficial cost
rationalisation.
...
[411] The second reason to account for productivity efficiency
gains flowing to foreign owners from a merger is that to
do otherwise would
effectively discriminate against such shareholders in comparison with domestic
shareholders. Placing foreign
owned businesses at a relative disadvantage in
merger authorisations, would create a disincentive for foreigners to undertake
investment
into New Zealand more generally. Such a disincentive could be
detrimental given the wider benefits that arise from inbound foreign
investment.
These benefits include a higher stock of available capital and lower cost of
capital for the New Zealand economy, as
well as improved technology and
knowledge transfer.
[footnotes omitted]
[13] The Commission recognised that these feedback benefits were
unquantifiable and were unlikely to equate to the productive
efficiency gains
obtained by foreign shareholders from the merger. It nevertheless determined
that the feedback benefits should
be treated as offsetting the productive
efficiency benefits flowing offshore to Lempriere:
[415] Regarding the specific value of these feedback effects, the Commission acknowledges that the public benefits to New Zealand from these effects are unlikely to exactly equal the direct productive efficiency gains obtained by foreign shareholders from the merger. Although there is a
real possibility that the benefits from these feedback impacts may be
substantial, these effects may be unquantifiable. Nevertheless,
because of the
feedback effects identified, we do not consider it appropriate to exclude
efficiency gains to foreign owners,
consistent with the Court’s
view in AMPS-A.
[416] Therefore, we do not consider that in this case there is a
sufficiently strong rationale to depart from the approach that
has been endorsed
by the courts to date. For this reason, the following productive efficiency
benefits have been estimated and these
estimates included in their
entirety.
[footnotes omitted]
Submissions
[14] Mr Dixon argues that the Commission erred in adopting this approach.
He contends that the Commission should have excluded
from its quantitative
analysis the proportion of productivity gains that will flow offshore to
Lempriere. Because the feedback benefits
are unquantifiable, he argues that the
Commission should have considered them at the end of the exercise as
part of its
overall qualitative assessment. Mr Dixon submits that the
feedback benefits bear no correlation to the productive efficiency gains
flowing
to foreign shareholders and the Commission was wrong in effectively equating
them in its assessment. Mr Dixon further submits
that the Commission’s
approach is not consistent with the authorities.
[15] Mr Goddard QC submits that the Commission reached the orthodox result on this issue, consistent with authority, but it used a novel approach that is wrong in principle to get there. He submits that when assessing the benefit to the public, the Commission is required by s 3A of the Act to have regard to all efficiency gains that are likely to result from the acquisition. As a matter of principle, a company that is incorporated in New Zealand and carries on business in New Zealand forms part of the general public and the general laws apply to it regardless of its ownership from time to time. Mr Goddard submits that there is no suggestion in Parts 2 or 3 of the Act that it is intended to distinguish between participants in New Zealand markets by reference to their nationality or ownership. For example, he notes that the purpose provision in s 1A refers to consumers “within New Zealand”, being all consumers regardless of their nationality or ownership. Mr Goddard argues that this analysis is also confirmed by s 69A of the Act which makes clear that the Commission cannot
require an undertaking in relation to ownership of an applicant, or impose
any such condition on the grant of an authorisation.
[16] Mr Goddard submits that all sorts of practical difficulties would
arise if the Commission were required to consider the ownership
of an acquirer:
At what date would ownership be assessed? How would the Commission treat a
publicly listed company where shareholdings
may change frequently? Would the
Commission need to consider the residency of shareholders of corporate
shareholders? Would
the Commission need to consider the residency of
beneficiaries of trusts holding shares in an acquirer?
[17] Moreover, Mr Goddard submits that it has not been the Commission’s practice since AMPS-A was decided in 1991, to discount efficiency gains achieved by New Zealand companies carrying on business in New Zealand merely because that company has a foreign shareholder. He submits that AMPS-A is authority for the proposition that benefits flowing to foreign shareholders should be disregarded and he says that this was the approach followed in Air New Zealand v Commerce
Commission (No 6).8
[18] Mr Dunning QC disagrees with both Mr Dixon and Mr Goddard in their
respective interpretations of these authorities. He
submits that the
Commission’s approach, differentiating between functionless monopoly
rents (which should be excluded)
and other benefits (which should not be
excluded), is in accordance with the authorities.
[19] In summary, all three parties rely on the same authorities to support their fundamentally different contentions as to the correct approach to benefits accruing to foreign shareholders: Cavalier argues that these should be counted in every case; Godfrey Hirst argues that they should be disregarded in every case; and the
Commission contends that it depends on the nature of the
benefit.
8 Air New Zealand v Commerce Commission (No 6) (2004) 11 TCLR 347 (HC).
Analysis
[20] There is a paucity of authority dealing with the issue of how to
treat benefits to foreign shareholders. The leading authority
is the decision
of this Court in 1991 in AMPS-A. That case involved an application by
Telecom for authorisation to acquire management rights to the AMPS-A radio
frequency band
for use for cellular telephone services in New Zealand. The
Commission heavily discounted efficiency gains or cost savings that
would accrue
to Telecom from the acquisition because it was 80 per cent foreign owned. The
High Court upheld the Commission’s
decision to decline authorisation but
rejected its approach to the benefits accruing to foreign
shareholders.
[21] Because all parties refer to AMPS-A to support their
respective contentions as to the correct approach on the issue of returns to
foreign shareholders, it is helpful
to set out the Court’s discussion of
the issue in full:9
We turn to consider a related issue that was raised by both Telecom and by
counsel for the commission. This is how to treat the
benefit to foreign
shareholders versus the New Zealand public. The point arises from the
commission’s discounting of efficiency
gains or cost savings to Telecom
because “the bulk of the gain will be realised by Telecom’s largely
overseas owners”.
It did not disregard them but gave them weight
“to only a minimal extent” (see Decision 254 paras 142 and
144(a)(vii)).
The foundation for this view was the commission’s finding that:
“Since the most certain period for the realisation of these gains is
the short-term future, and since the New Zealand shareholding
in Telecom is
likely to be a small minority during that period, the public benefit from the
gains must be discounted accordingly”.
Telecom’s evidence was that New Zealand ownership over the estimated
relevant period was 20 percent though that was said to
be conservative. There
was no suggestion to us that any other estimate should be taken into account.
That is a small minority.
The issue of principle is whether efficiency gains and cost savings accruing
solely to foreign shareholders are necessarily to be
ignored as public benefits
or at least to be largely discounted. It is to be observed that the commission
did not disregard, in
this connection, any gains and savings accruing
potentially to New Zealand consumers, suppliers, and employees.
The Act has an express New Zealand orientation. Both the long title and the
definition of “market” refer to New Zealand
and there is, on the
other hand, distinct provision about Australia; s 26A(a), (b) and (c).
9 Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce Commission, above n 7, at 531.
Decisions as to dominance, its acquisition, and strengthening, are
thus limited to the relevant market in New Zealand.
Public detriment, which
includes the result of the dominance or its strengthening, to that extent is
limited to New Zealand results.
Moreover, any inquiry and weighing of public
detriment or public benefit beyond New Zealand would be difficult, problematic
and
unlikely to be of any meaningful benefit.
Nevertheless, what redounds to the benefit of New Zealand society is not
necessarily immediately obvious. We reject any view that
profits earned by
overseas investment in this country are necessarily to be regarded as a drain on
New Zealand. New Zealand
seeks to be a member of a liberal
multilateral trading and investment community. Consistent with this stance, we
observe
that improvements in international efficiency create gains from trade
and investment which, from a long-run perspective,
benefit the New
Zealand public.
On the other hand, if there are circumstances in which the exercise of market
power gives rise to functionless monopoly rents, supranormal
profits that arise
neither from cost savings nor from innovation, and which accrue to overseas
shareholders, we think it right to
regard these as an exploitation of the New
Zealand community and to be counted as a detriment to the New Zealand
public.
While this approach to benefit to foreign investors can, we think, be
justified on quite general and fundamental grounds, its appropriateness
is
reinforced by the insertion of s 3A into the Commerce Act.
[22] Section 3A of the Act provides:
3A Commission to consider efficiency
Where the Commission is required under this Act to determine whether or not,
or the extent to which, conduct will result, or will
be likely to result, in a
benefit to the public, the Commission shall have regard to any efficiencies that
the Commission considers
will result, or will be likely to result, from that
conduct.
[23] We do not consider that the reference in this section to any efficiencies that the Commission considers will result, or will be likely to result, means that the Commission is obliged to disregard any consequent supra-competitive returns to foreign shareholders. This section was inserted to counter any suggestion that might be taken from the reference to “the long-term benefit of consumers within New Zealand” in the purpose section of the Act (s 1A), that public benefits are confined to direct consumer welfare.
[24] Despite rejecting the Commission’s approach of
discounting benefits to foreign shareholders, the High Court
in AMPS-A
concluded that the detriments outweighed the benefits and accordingly upheld
the Commission’s decision:10
Thus in this instance both benefits and detriments are almost entirely
efficiency gains and losses. We endorse the commission’s
conclusion that
the competitive detriments from the strengthening of dominance in this market
outweigh any public benefit flowing
from the acquisition.
Although we have rejected the commission’s discounting of
benefits by reason of their overseas character, we find this
an easy conclusion
to reach. On the side of detriment to the public are all those likelihoods of
allocative and dynamic inefficiency
that we have discussed, a much larger set
than those considered by the commission. On the side of benefit to the public
are the
likelihoods of some production or technical efficiencies, discounted
however by the reason of the likelihood of an enhanced
propensity to
internal inefficiency on the part of Telecom by reason of the strengthening of
its dominance.
[25] The High Court’s decision was reversed by a full court of the Court of Appeal which unanimously concluded that the public benefits outweighed the detriments and that Telecom should be authorised to acquire the AMPS-A management right.11 However, despite the decision being reversed, the High Court’s approach to benefits accruing to foreign shareholders does not appear to have been challenged by any of the parties and is not criticised in any of the five judgments.
For the reasons that follow, we consider that it is safe to assume that, had
there been any disagreement with the approach taken to
this issue in the High
Court, it would have been addressed.
[26] Cooke P quoted the passages from the High Court judgment set out at [24] above confirming the Court’s rejection of the Commission’s approach in discounting benefits to foreign shareholders. His only expressed disagreement with what the High Court said in those passages was the suggestion that the balancing exercise was
easy on the facts of that case:12
What is required by the legislation is a balancing exercise, a comparison
between likely public benefit from the acquisition
and likely public
detriment from the strengthening of Telecom’s dominant position in either
market. In respectful disagreement
with what was said by the High Court
in
10 Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce Commission, above n 7, at 534.
11 Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce Commission, above n 4.
12 Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce Commission, above n 4, at 435.
McKay J stated at 449 that he shared Cooke P’s view that the balancing exercise was not an easy one on the facts of that case.
the course of the passage about to be quoted, I do not find the exercise at
all easy.
[27] Cooke P noted that the expert retained by Telecom, Dr A E Bollard,
estimated “the economies of scope and scale which
would arise from Telecom
rather than a competitor managing AMPS-A as well as AMPS-B and spreading its
overheads across a larger business
base ... together with improved returns to
the shareholders at a broad value of about $100 million.” Although Cooke P
stated
that he was sceptical of the accuracy of such estimates, he accepted that
“there can be no doubt that some significant economies
are likely”.
Despite the significant economies and consequent return to shareholders, there
is no indication in any of the
judgments that the Court applied any discount to
these benefits on account of the 80 per cent foreign shareholding. If the
benefits
accruing to Telecom’s foreign shareholders should have been
discounted contrary to the approach taken in the High Court, this
would have
required special attention by the Court of Appeal as part of what it regarded as
a difficult balancing exercise.
[28] We reject Mr Dixon’s submission that the High Court’s
decision in AMPS-A was implicitly overruled by the Court of Appeal. Mr
Dixon relies on the following observations made by Richardson J at the
conclusion
of his judgment:13
The second is that both the commission and the Court accepted that the
relevant benefits and detriments were almost entirely efficiency
gains and
losses. In these circumstances the balancing process does not give rise to the
obvious problems of quantifying and then
weighing disparate public interest
considerations.
The third is the desirability of quantifying benefits and detriments where
and to the extent that it is feasible to do so. The commission
encourages
applicants to quantify anticipated public benefits. In this case certain major
efficiency gains were quantified for Telecom
at some $75 million. While both
the commission and the Court did not accept elements in that quantification,
both bodies considered
that there would be significant efficiency gains if
Telecom had management rights over both AMPS-A and AMPS-B. In those
circumstances
there is in my view a responsibility on a regulatory body to
attempt so far as possible to quantify detriments and benefits rather
than
rely on a purely intuitive judgment to justify a conclusion that
detriments in fact exceed quantified benefits.
[29] This observation was made in the context of the Commission’s
conclusion
that the significant economies that had been quantified in the expert
evidence led by
13 Telecom Corporation of New Zealand Ltd v Commerce Commission, above n 7, at 446-447.
Telecom should be discounted because of “the likelihood of an enhanced
propensity to internal inefficiency on the part of Telecom
by reason of the
strengthening of its dominance”. Richardson J’s criticism was that
the Commission should have attempted
to quantify these inefficiencies rather
than relying solely on intuition.
[30] If Mr Dixon is correct that returns to foreign shareholders must be
quantified and excluded from the assessment of public
benefit and any offsetting
feedback benefits factored in at the end of the process as part of the
qualitative assessment, that exercise
would have been undertaken by the Court of
Appeal in AMPS-A. The Court would then have faced the problem of
quantifying and weighing disparate public interest considerations. The fact
that
this was not done, coupled with Richardson J’s observation that no
quantification problems arose in that case, further supports
the conclusion that
the Court did not consider it appropriate to discount returns to foreign capital
derived from efficiency gains
and losses.
[31] We were advised from the bar that the Commission has consistently
applied AMPS-A in all subsequent authorisation cases, as it was bound to
do. The Commission’s published guidelines refer to and adopt the
approach set out in the AMPS-A decision.14
[32] The High Court’s approach in AMPS-A was followed by this Court in Air New Zealand v Commerce Commission (No 6).15 That case concerned an application by Qantas to purchase 22.5 per cent of the voting equity capital of Air New Zealand and an interdependent application by Air New Zealand for authorisation of a proposed strategic alliance arrangement. No discount was applied to reflect the foreign shareholding in that case. The exercise that Mr Dixon submits is necessary in such cases, of quantifying and excluding the return to the foreign shareholder and then considering any feedback benefits as part of the qualitative
assessment, was not undertaken.
14 See Commerce Commission Authorisation Gjuidelines (July 2013) at [53]-[55]. These Guidelines replaced the Commerce Commission’s Guidelines to the analysis of Public Benefits and Detriments which were issued in 1994 and revised in December 1997.
15 Air New Zealand v Commerce Commission (No 6), above n 8.
[33] The Court’s endorsement of the approach taken by the
Commission in that case, consistent with AMPS-A, appears from the
following passages in the judgment in Air New Zealand:
[242] ... Transfers between New Zealand and other countries are not
necessarily regarded as welfare neutral.
We interpolate that this is consistent with the general rule set out in
AMPS-A and the exception to it arising out of functionless monopoly
rents.
...
[316] ... the Commission agreed to ignore the capital payment to Air New
Zealand from Qantas and as a corollary to disregard the
share of Air New Zealand
profits payable to Qantas for the purpose of calculating welfare
losses.
This is consistent with the general rule in AMPS-A.
[34] The AMPS-A approach to returns to foreign shareholders was
also followed by the Australian Competition Tribunal in Qantas Airways
Limited.16 After quoting the key passages from the High
Court’s decision in AMPS-A, the Tribunal stated:
[198] We are guided by the treatment in the New Zealand jurisprudence of
benefits accruing to foreign-owned corporations and their
shareholders in the
assessment of public benefits.
[199] Accordingly, we concluded that, where we are satisfied that the
Alliance would be likely to result in a lessening of competition,
any associated
supra-competitive returns likely to accrue to Qantas’ foreign
shareholders (due, for example, to higher
fares or reduced capacity which, by
definition, involve an income transfer from consumers, including Australian
consumers), should
not be regarded as a public benefit for the purposes of s 90.
This would include any cost savings retained by Qantas for the benefit
of its
foreign shareholders which constituted such supra- competitive returns.
(Similarly, any deadweight loss associated with higher
fares or reduced capacity
that accrues to Qantas’ foreign shareholders should also be disregarded,
as this does not constitute
a detriment to the Australian public). However, we
acknowledge that, in some circumstances returns to foreign shareholders of
Australian companies may be re-invested in the Australian economy or
might result in further foreign investment in
Australia, in which case
there would be a public benefit for the purposes of s
90.
16 Qantas Airways Limited [2004] ACompT 9, [2004] ATPR 42-027, [2005] ATPR 42-065.
[35] While we understand that standard economic practice, as reflected in
the Commission’s practice before the AMPS-A decision, is to
discount payments to foreigners in calculating domestic welfare, that is
just practice and is not a fundamental economic principle or a necessary
consequence of economic analysis. The statements of principle
set out in the
High Court’s decision in AMPS-A concerning the treatment of returns
to foreign shareholders were tacitly endorsed by a full court of the Court of
Appeal and have
since been followed both here and in Australia. It is now 25
years since the Court of Appeal’s judgment in AMPS-A was delivered.
We were not referred to any authority doubting its correctness. We expect that
Parliament would have amended the Act
if it was concerned that the statements of
principle set out in AMPS-A were contrary to its intention, particularly
given that these have been consistently applied by the Commission for the past
25 years
in accordance with its published guidelines.
[36] It follows that we are unable to accept Mr Goddard’s
submission that foreign shareholding is to be disregarded in every
case, even
where the returns represent supra-competitive profits. We are also unable to
accept Mr Dixon’s submission that
returns to foreign capital should be
excluded in every case, even where these do not represent supra-competitive
profits. We accept
Mr Dunning’s submission that, as a matter of principle,
consistent with AMPS-A and subsequent authorities, any supra- competitive
return to foreign capital should not be taken into account as a benefit to the
public of New Zealand. We would add that it does not matter whether the supra-
competitive return results from increased prices
or efficiency gains. However,
if the return on capital does not constitute a supra-competitive return
but simply incentivises
competitiveness, efficiency, innovation and
investment, AMPS-A provides no justification for discounting that part
of the return which accrues to foreign capital.
[37] The Commission concluded that production efficiencies would not give
rise to functionless monopoly rents and accordingly
did not discount them to
reflect the foreign shareholding:
[413] We consider that the domestic scouring sector faces a non-trivial competitive constraint from offshore scours and this competitive pressure may well increase over time. Furthermore, the degree of international
transferability of scouring services and the ability for scouring activities
to relocate to different countries, such as has
occurred with the
Australian scouring sector, means that without ongoing productivity
improvements, ongoing competitive pressure
could ultimately see the
closure of the domestic scouring sector.
[414] Therefore, we consider that productivity gains to the
domestic scouring sector are unlikely to constitute functionless
economic rents,
at the very least over the medium to long-term.
[38] Godfrey Hirst does not challenge this finding.
Accordingly, the Commission’s treatment of returns
to foreign
shareholders from these productivity gains is consistent with long-standing
authority and is correct.
[39] By contrast, the Commission discounted likely scouring price increases to the extent that these would flow to Cavalier’s foreign shareholder.17 This was because the Commission expects these price increases to be absorbed by New Zealand farmers and merchants thereby constituting a wealth transfer from New Zealanders to foreigners without any corresponding exchange of value as set by a competitive market. In short, the Commission regarded these likely price increases as being a
functionless monopoly rent. This treatment is also consistent with the authorities. [40] For the reasons given, this ground of appeal must fail.
Did the Commission underestimate the likely price
increases?
[41] The Commission considered that the increased market power Cavalier
would obtain as a result of the acquisition would enable
it to raise scouring
prices:
(a) by between five and 15 per cent for wool destined for
export;
(b) by between five and 25 per cent for wool scoured for Godfrey
Hirst;
and
(c) by up to 10 per cent for wool grease sold to domestic
consumers.18
17 Final Determination at [607]-[624].
[42] Godfrey Hirst challenges only the first of these assessments. It
contends that the range of likely scouring price increase
for wool destined for
export would be more in the region of 10 to 20 per cent.
[43] Godfrey Hirst claims that the Commission reached its incorrect
assessment as a result of two errors. First, the interviews
conducted with
merchants were deficient because the wrong questions were asked, in the wrong
way, leading to speculative responses.
Second, the Commission failed to
analyse the responses correctly and overlooked or wrongly discounted evidence
supporting higher
price increases.
[44] Mr Dixon took us carefully through the particular passages in the
various interviews which he contends support Godfrey Hirst’s
submission.
He notes that in some instances, merchants were invited to engage in
“crystal ball gazing” and “complete
guesswork”, even to
the point of “throwing a dart at the dartboard”. He submits that
other questions were too
imprecise to yield useful answers, for example when
merchants were asked to comment on how they would be likely to react to a
“whopping
great price increase” or a “ridiculous
price”.
[45] While there is validity in these criticisms, the examples given are
the product of Godfrey Hirst’s careful scrutiny
of the records and
transcripts of all of the interviews conducted during the course of a lengthy
investigation and are not representative
of the interviews overall.
Further, the questioning necessarily required merchants to speculate on how
the market would
be likely to react to price increases of varying levels. We
see nothing wrong with the Commission seeking merchants' views about
that.
[46] Even if there were shortcomings in the interview process, this does
not materially assist Godfrey Hirst because the appeal
is conducted on the
record. This ground of appeal can only succeed if Godfrey Hirst can persuade
the Court, based on the record,
that the Commission’s assessment was
wrong.
[47] Mr Dixon accepts that there is ample evidence to support the range of price increases adopted by the Commission. However, he says that this is not the point. He argues that the Commission should have placed greater weight on the evidence of
the price increases the merchants said they could bear rather than their
speculation as to what the monopoly scour might do. He
contends that the
evidence as to the former indicates that the price increase is likely to be more
in the region of 10 to 20 per
cent.
[48] We accept Mr Dixon’s submission that there was evidence from a
number of
merchants that could support an inference that the price increase could be as
high as
20 per cent. However, it does not follow that the Commission was
wrong in reaching its assessment that the likely price
increase will be
lower.
[49] The Commission reached its conclusion about the likely price increases following an extensive investigative process. This included interviewing 13 out of a total of approximately 35 buyers of scouring services in New Zealand who together account for [ ] per cent of all scoured wool purchased in New Zealand.19 Initial interviews were conducted between November 2014 and March 2015. A further round of interviews took place in July 2015 and there were additional follow-up
interviews in September 2015. Most merchants were interviewed at least
twice, one was interviewed three times and another, four times.
In all, the
Commission conducted a total of 21 merchant interviews.
[50] When conducting these interviews the investigators acknowledged that
the task of accurately predicting future price increases
in the event of the
acquisition proceeding was inherently difficult and speculative. The
information gathered from the interviews
was necessarily imperfect and
suffered from obvious limitations. However, we are not persuaded that the
Commission should
have disregarded, or placed little weight on, the
merchants’ views on the likely price increase. Their views, as key
market
participants, are relevant and will have provided some assistance
to the Commission in making its assessment.
[51] It must be kept in mind that the Commission conducts an investigation, not a court process limited by evidential rules. For the purposes of carrying out its functions under the Act, the Commission has been given broad powers to receive any statement, document or information that may assist its determination regardless of
whether it would be admissible in a court.20 Interviews with
market participants will be conducted with varying degrees of formality,
depending on the circumstances. Almost inevitably,
the Commission will receive
information during the investigation process of varying quality.
[52] The Commission may attribute little or no weight to some of the
information it gathers and place greater weight on other
information that it
considers to be more reliable. However, the Commission does not make its
assessment simply by accepting or
rejecting the speculative views of market
participants or by collating the merchants’ responses and determining the
range of
likely price increases accordingly. Rather, the Commission is required
to exercise its own expert judgment. This will be based,
not only on
information gathered during the investigation, but on its own knowledge of the
industry and the dynamics of the particular
market or markets. The
Commission’s assessment need not necessarily coincide with the
views expressed by market participants.
[53] The Commission has a good understanding of the relevant markets, not only as a result of its lengthy investigation for the purposes of the present application, but also as a result of its consideration of an earlier similar application in 2011.21 The Commission considered that demand for clean wool from New Zealand is likely to continue to reduce over time because of the global shift in the manufacture of wool products to Asia, the increasing quantity and quality of scouring capacity in that region, and the growing substitution of synthetics for wool products, particularly by domestic carpet manufacturers.22 The Commission noted that wool merchants operate on narrow margins and have limited ability to absorb price increases themselves.23 The Commission considered that it is unlikely that merchants would be able to pass on any post acquisition increases in scouring prices downstream to wool users in export markets.24 This is because wool scoured in New Zealand must compete in an international market with wool scoured in other countries as well as
with other fibres, including synthetic fibres. The Commission also
considered that
20 Commerce Act 1986, s 99.
21 Cavalier Wool Holdings Ltd [2011] NZ ComCom 12: Decision No 725.
22 At [214].
23 At [330].
24 At [325] – [326].
any attempt to pass the price increase upstream to farmers would be
constrained by competition from exporters of greasy
wool.25
[54] The Commission concluded that Cavalier’s ability to increase
scouring prices following the acquisition would be constrained
to a greater or
lesser extent by: the ability of wool merchants to increase their exports of
greasy wool for scouring overseas, particularly
in China;26
Cavalier’s need to maintain volume in a declining industry;27
the prospect of entry by a new scouring operator;28 and the
prospect of Godfrey Hirst shifting its wool manufacturing business
offshore.29 Godfrey Hirst does not challenge these contextual
conclusions regarding the dynamics of the relevant markets.
[55] The Commission assumed that the maximum price increase of 15 per
cent would occur immediately after the acquisition.30 However, it
considered that this was a conservative approach that was likely to
over-estimate the detriments because post-merger price
increases at the upper
end of the scale were likely to be imposed in incremental steps over time
and not as an “immediate,
one-off substantial
increase”.31 The Commission also paired the highest chosen
demand elasticity of -1 with the highest prospective price change when assessing
the
likely detriment. This was also a conservative approach, tending to
over-estimate the likely detriment if anything.
[56] Taking all of these matters into account, we are not persuaded that the Commission’s expert judgment, in adopting a range of likely price increases for wool destined for export of five to 15 per cent, was wrong. This ground of appeal also
fails.
25 At [331].
26 At [332].
27 At [287].
28 At [223] – [224].
29 At [574].
30 At [581].
31 At [283], [581] and [582].
Should the Commission have disregarded the benefits from closing
Kaputone?
[57] In its first draft determination, the Commission accepted
that if the acquisition did not proceed, the parties
would continue to operate
their existing businesses separately. Godfrey Hirst responded by suggesting
that the Commission should
consider another likely counterfactual, that Cavalier
would close Clive and NZWSI would close its South Island operation at Kaputone
and consolidate its operations in the North Island. Following further
investigation, the Commission accepted Godfrey Hirst’s
submission in
relation to Clive and disregarded the benefits of closing that plant on the
basis that it was likely to happen whether
or not the merger proceeded.
However, the Commission found that Kaputone was not likely to close unless the
acquisition proceeded
and accordingly did not exclude these
benefits.
[58] Godfrey Hirst does not challenge the Commission’s conclusion
that NZWSI is likely to continue its South Island operation
if the acquisition
does not go ahead. However, it now submits that the Commission ought to have
considered another counterfactual,
where the Kaputone operation is not closed
but, instead, is relocated to Timaru.
[59] This suggested counterfactual was not promoted to the Commission by Godfrey Hirst or any other party. Nevertheless, we do not accept the submissions advanced on behalf of Cavalier and the Commission that this precludes consideration of the issue on this appeal. It is the Commission’s responsibility to identify the relevant counterfactuals against which to assess the application. If it could be demonstrated from the record that the Commission failed to do so, this would be a judicially reviewable error and would be amenable to correction on appeal. Mr Goddard and Mr Dunning retreated from their written submissions on this point and did not seriously contend that the Court could not consider the issue in the context of an appeal so long as the error was apparent on the face of the record. However, they argue that the Court should have no difficulty concluding that this counterfactual is not supported by the evidence and that explains why the Commission did not consider it and no one pursued it.
[60] The Commission found that over the next two to three years,
additional capital expenditure of at least [ ] would be
required to [
] and an additional [ ] to [ ]. Mr Dixon argues that in these
circumstances there is a compelling
business case to support relocating the
Kaputone operation to Timaru. This would avoid the [ ] at Kaputone and
the [
], assessed by the Commission at between [ ] per
annum. It would also enable the land at Kaputone, now zoned
residential, to be
released for a higher value use, leaving NZWSI free to purchase land at lower
cost in Timaru. In the light of
these savings, and given the planned move to
Timaru if the acquisition proceeds, Mr Dixon contends that the Commission ought
to have
identified and considered this as a likely counterfactual even though
Godfrey Hirst and its experts did not.
[61] Mr Dixon’s submission confronts the immediate difficulty that
there is no evidence that NZWSI gave any consideration
to the possibility of
relocating the plant at Kaputone to Timaru, or anywhere else, prior to the
proposed acquisition. To the contrary,
the evidence strongly supports the
Commission’s conclusion that if the acquisition does not proceed, NZWSI
will upgrade its
existing operation at Kaputone rather than close it down and
set up somewhere else.
[62] In 2013, prior to considering the proposed acquisition, [
] at Kaputone. [ ] per
annum and NZWSI expected
that it would [ ] of completing the necessary
upgrades.
[63] Before reaching its factual findings regarding Kaputone, the Commission thoroughly tested NZWSI’s claims concerning the proposed upgrade. It engaged independent experts to report on the necessity, viability and cost of the proposed solution and to consider whether there were any other more cost effective solutions. The Commission was advised that NZWSI’s proposal was technically viable, no better solutions were available and it was satisfied that the increased profitability
resulting from the [ ] would justify the
investment.32
[64] In summary, there is ample evidence to support the
Commission’s finding
that NZWSI will upgrade Kaputone and continue its operations there if authorisation
is not granted. In the absence of any evidence to show that NZWSI was even remotely considering the possibility of establishing a new operation at Timaru instead of upgrading its existing operation, we consider that the Commission cannot be criticised for not examining this possibility. It had not been heralded in either of the earlier draft determinations, had not been raised by anyone during the course of the 12 month investigation and was not supported by the evidence. The Commission could not have found that there was a real chance of this scenario occurring without referring the matter back to the parties for further submissions. It must be kept in mind that the entire authorisation process is normally expected to be completed
within 60 working days.33 This indicates that the Commission
is not required to
chase down every conceivable possibility, irrespective of whether it has been
considered by the applicant or identified by any other
party.
[65] For the reasons we have given, we are not persuaded that the
Commission was wrong in not finding that there is a real chance
that NZWSI will
close Kaputone and establish a new operation at Timaru if the acquisition does
not proceed. This ground of appeal
also fails.
[66] The appeal must accordingly be dismissed and it is therefore not
necessary for us to consider the grounds raised by Cavalier
to support the
determination on other grounds. However, in case the matter goes further, we
briefly do so.
Did the Commission overestimate the likely redundancy costs at
Kaputone?
[67] There is no dispute that the Commission overestimated the likely
redundancy costs at Kaputone. The correct figure based
on Cavalier’s
evidence is [ ], not [ ] as assessed by the Commission.
Was the Commission correct to disregard the benefits of closing
Clive?
[68] The Commission identified two counterfactual scenarios regarding the
Clive plant:
141 Based on the information provided by Cavalier discussed above, we consider that there is more than one likely without-the-acquisition scenario regarding Clive.
141.1 There is a real chance that without the merger Cavalier would retain
its scouring plant in Clive and continue to run it in
peak periods.
141.2 There is also a real chance that, without the merger, Cavalier would
close or sell the Clive site in the near future.
[69] In accordance with its interpretation of the High
Court’s decision in Woolworths & Ors v Commerce Commission,
the Commission conducted its analysis on the basis of the closure scenario
giving rise to the most acute competition concern.34 The Commission
therefore excluded all benefits of closing Clive from its analysis. These
benefits were assessed as being in the range
from [ ].
[70] Mr Goddard submits that the Commission misapplied Woolworths because that was a clearance case decided under s 66 of the Act where an applicant is required to satisfy the Commission that there will not be any substantial lessening of competition, comparing the factual against all counterfactuals. In that context, it is appropriate to consider the counterfactual giving rise to the most acute competition concerns because the Commission must be satisfied that a substantial lessening of
competition is not likely.35 If the Commission is not satisfied
of this, it must decline
clearance. By contrast, in assessing an application for an authorisation, Mr
Goddard submits that the Commission is obliged to consider
all benefits and
detriments that have a real chance of occurring and weigh these by taking into
account the likelihood of their occurrence
and the reliability of the
quantification. Accordingly, he submits that the Commission ought to have taken
into account the increased
probability that Clive will be closed if the
acquisition proceeds; a certainty that it will close in the factual compared
with a
real chance, but less than a certainty, that it will close in the
counterfactual.
[71] Only efficiency gains that are merger-specific can be considered.
If the posited efficiency gain can be achieved without
the merger and is likely
to occur anyway, it does not qualify for consideration.
[72] The evidence shows that Clive has had [
].36 [ ]
and has accounted for only [ ] per cent of Cavalier’s North
Island volumes over the
34 Woolworths & Ors v Commerce Commission [2007] NZHC 1351; (2008) 8 NZBLC 102,128 (HC) at [122].
35 Commerce Commission v Woolworths Ltd [2008] NZCA 276, (2008) 12 TCLR 194 (CA) at 207.
past four years. While the Commission accepted
that there was a chance that Clive would be retained if the acquisition did
not
proceed to cover any peak season capacity constraints and annual
maintenance shutdowns at Awatoto, its closure is not a merger-specific
benefit
in the required sense. The efficiency gains available from closing Clive can be
achieved without the merger and Cavalier
has deferred consideration of whether
it will do so until after the result of this authorisation application has been
finally determined.
[73] We are not persuaded that the Commission was wrong to
disregard the claimed benefits of closing Clive.
Result
[74] The appeal is dismissed.
[75] All parties agree that this is a category 3 case for costs purposes. It is categorised accordingly. If the parties are unable to agree the issue of costs,
sequential memoranda should be
filed.
M A Gilbert J
Addendum
[76] The unredacted version of this judgment was released to counsel and
their solicitors on 8 June 2016 to enable them to advise
those parts of the
judgment which ought to be redacted from the public version of the judgment on
grounds of confidentiality and
commercial sensitivity.
[77] Counsel have sought redaction on these grounds to parts of the
following paragraphs in the judgment: paras [49], [60], [62],
[63], [67], [69],
[72].
[78] I am satisfied that these redactions should made to the judgment for
reasons of confidentiality and commercial sensitivity.
[79] The judgment with these redactions may now be released and published.
NZLII:
Copyright Policy
|
Disclaimers
|
Privacy Policy
|
Feedback
URL: http://www.nzlii.org/nz/cases/NZHC/2016/1262.html