Home
| Databases
| WorldLII
| Search
| Feedback
Public Interest Law Journal of New Zealand |
Last Updated: 1 August 2024
16 Public Interest Law Journal of New Zealand (2023)
161
Public Interest Law Journal of New Zealand
(2023) 10 PILJNZ 16
ARTICLE
Life’s Not Fair, but Pharmac Is: Defending Pharmac from Its Critics
CONNOR BROWNE*
New Zealand’s Pharmaceutical Management Agency (Pharmac) was recently subject to review. The review was instigated by interest groups’ lobbying. This article explores the political environment of this review through the application of interest-group theory. Four case studies are used to reveal the personal interests of politicians, disease interest groups and pharmaceutical lobbyists. I argue that the criticisms of Pharmac surrounding the review have little weight and come from private interest groups. Pharmac’s apolitical model has been highly successful and needs to be preserved.
I Introduction
In 2010, a patient was admitted to Auckland City Hospital. The patient was a 15-year-old male suffering from severe Crohn’s disease, an autoimmune condition that inflames the digestive system. The young man was in a serious condition, suffering from dehydration and malnourishment. He had been diagnosed with Crohn’s only two months prior and had already lost 10 kg. So far, all treatments had proved ineffective, and only two remained. The first option was surgery to remove the inflamed parts of the bowel, which could lead to lifelong complications. The second was new biologic medications that could target the rogue parts of his immune system. But there was a catch; the patient was told these new treatments were costly—upwards of $100,000 per year. Fortunately, the patient was in New Zealand, and Pharmac funded these medications. Doctors administered the new drug to the patient, who made a dramatic improvement. It took some time, but the patient could live a full life, attend university, and write this very article you are reading
* BA/LLB(Hons), University of Auckland, Junior Barrister at Shortland Chambers. I would like to thank Professor Jianlin Chen of the University of Melbourne for his feedback on my article. I would also like to thank my parents for their enduring support of me and my struggles with Crohn’s Disease.
now. I have shared my story to illustrate the profound positive impact that Pharmac has had on people’s lives.
Despite the enormous good that Pharmac does, it regularly receives harsh criticism in the media. It is common to read stories about patients who suffer from terminal illnesses and unfortunately do not have potentially life-saving treatments funded as I did.1 Notwithstanding the negative media attention, Pharmac has maintained an apolitical decision-making process. There have been only two instances where the New Zealand Government has capitulated to public pressure and overruled a Pharmac decision not to fund medications.2
In March 2021, the Labour-led Government announced that it would review Pharmac.3 This article was written before the report was released, but has been updated to address some of the implications and consequences of the review.4 I will focus on Pharmac’s role in the New Zealand healthcare system and the political forces that surround its current review. I argue that Pharmac should retain its apolitical status and that there is a risk that this might be lost, and to an extent it might have been. Applying the public choice and interest group theory model, I argue that certain interest groups will attempt to change Pharmac for their benefit.
Four case studies are used to illustrate the political pressure that interest groups can exert on government decision-making. I argue that groups that advocate for funding expensive treatments for serious illnesses (disease interest groups), typically rare diseases, are more likely to affect government intervention successfully, as these interest groups can gather significant media attention and political momentum. In addition to these rare disease interest groups, pharmaceutical lobbyists continually criticise Pharmac’s decision-making processes. I will argue that the combination of these forces creates a dangerous political environment in which to review Pharmac.
In Part II, I will review the history and role of Pharmac. In Part III, I will explore the current Pharmac review and the political pressure on the Government. In Part IV, I will explore four case studies. In Part V, I will explain public choice theory and apply to it the case studies. In Part VI, I will make recommendations about what changes to Pharmac should be avoided. In Part VII, I will briefly consider the effect of some the changes the review has brought.
II History, Objectives and Processes of Pharmac
A History and purposes
In the early 1990s, the Government was on a warpath of austerity measures.5 Cost-cutting occurred in all parts of government spending, and one such area was pharmaceutical spending. In 1993, the Government created Pharmac, an agency designed to centralise the
nation’s purchasing and funding of medications.6 Since then, it has accrued more purchasing responsibility and is now effectively a monopsony; it is the sole purchaser of medications in New Zealand.7 Being the sole purchaser has meant that Pharmac has had an effective bargaining position with pharmaceutical companies.
Consequently, Pharmac has been highly successful in reducing costs and enlarging the range of available medications for New Zealanders. Compared to the United Kingdom and Australia, New Zealand pays 30 per cent less for the same medications.8 In one notable example, Australia pays 13 times more than New Zealand does for the commonly prescribed atorvastatin.9
Pharmac has been successful in its original objective—to obtain the best price for medications. However, Pharmac’s role is broader than mere cost reduction; it has at least two other important and related objectives.10 First, it is responsible for ensuring an optimal range of medications for New Zealanders, known as the Pharmaceutical Schedule (the Schedule).11 Pharmac has a complex set of criteria that an expert board applies to ensure that New Zealand has the “best health outcomes”.12 Secondly, Pharmac directs the Exceptional Circumstance Scheme to manage drug funding for rare diseases.13
B Processes
To ensure the “best health outcomes” and efficient spending, Pharmac has a four-factor consideration system. The four factors are:14
Each factor has three aspects: the individual; the family, whānau and society; and the health system. Pharmac employs two common tools to analyse and apply the criteria: “maximum quality-adjusted life-years” (QALYs) and cost–utility analysis.15In explaining the old Pharmac criteria, members of the Pharmac board stated that they do not subscribe to any distributive approach, such as utilitarianism.16 Utilitarianism is a broad church, a theory of normative ethics that encompasses a diverse range of views and positions with the common theme being that the morally correct action is determined by
10 Cumming, Mays and Daubé, above n 2, at 1224. 11 At 1224.
16 At 1031.
its consequences.17 This is distinguished from other consequentialist theories (all of which define morality in terms of the consequences of actions) in that it focuses on maximising utility or, in more simple language, maximising happiness and minimising suffering. For example, undertaking a careful cost–benefit analysis of gains that a paralogical treatment offers in terms of its utility and reduction in suffering is unmistakeably utilitarian in nature. Pharmac did in practice use utilitarian analysis, such as when evaluating the gains in QALYs in the cost–utility calculation.18 The centrality of a utilitarian analysis in Pharmac’s decision-making serves to explain the difficult funding choices that Pharmac must make.
As mentioned earlier, there is consistent criticism about the lack of funding for rare (often terminal) diseases. As unfortunate as this is, it is the expected outcome for a decision-making process based on a utilitarian model. Utilitarianism is generally indifferent to individual suffering or hardship and is instead concerned with aggregate welfare.19 Consequently, a very unpleasant rare disease (such as cystic fibrosis) may inflict tremendous suffering on a handful of individuals. But, in the aggregate, the suffering will be significantly less than a more common but less severe condition (such as high cholesterol). The maximisation of QALYs for the best price possible will inevitably mean that those with rare diseases will have unfunded medications.
However, Pharmac is not entirely utilitarian in its decision-making. Pharmac does consider factors other than welfare, such as equity–efficiency trade-offs, to ensure that the QALYs do not accumulate in particular groups in society.20 Moreover, Pharmac manages the Exceptional Circumstances Scheme, which directly considers individual suffering that may have been overlooked by the utilitarian analysis used to manage the Schedule.21
Pharmac’s use of a utilitarian decision-making framework supplemented by non- utilitarian considerations shows that there will almost always be a justified and fair reason why we, unfortunately, do not always fund treatments for rare diseases. I will argue that we need to protect the apolitical decision-making role and utilitarian processes.
III Background to the Pharmac Review
The Pharmac review was announced in March 2021. The review was instigated in light of mounting criticisms of Pharmac, as the Terms of Reference explicitly state.22 Moreover, a review of Pharmac became a platform for the National Party during the 2020 election.23 Before exploring the current criticisms of Pharmac, it is useful to explain the parameters of the review.
A The terms of reference
The Terms of Reference outline two main areas of review. First, Pharmac’s level of effectiveness at meeting its current objectives.24 Secondly, whether Pharmac’s objectives
are best suited to maximise health outcomes.25 Several considerations are relevant to these two inquiries: Pharmac’s operating model, the extent of Pharmac’s responsibilities, the timeliness of funding decisions, transparency and how Pharmac compares to overseas models.26 There are three notable exclusions for the review: any commercial arrangements, Pharmac’s fixed budget and Pharmac’s independence.27
B Pharmac’s criticisms
Pharmac’s two most common criticisms are the failure to fund particular treatments and Pharmac’s slow uptake of new medications to the Schedule. These criticisms usually come from two distinct groups: interest groups for people suffering from a particular disease and their families; or pharmaceutical lobby groups.
(1) Failure to fund treatments
Funding criticisms and media coverage generally follow a similar pattern.28 A person will be suffering from a severe illness, and will have exhausted all currently offered treatments. There will be a promising new and expensive treatment that Pharmac is not currently funding. Some recent examples include Fiona Tolich’s battle for her son to receive treatment for spinal muscular atrophy;29 and the story of Jessica Port’s struggle with Crohn’s disease and the petition to fund ustekinumab.30 These stories, while tragic, are intended to evoke strong emotions and deep sympathy for those suffering. Pharmac is portrayed as an agency that is unfair and miserly in its decisions. For example, one headline read, “Pharmac ‘cruel’ for failing to fund drugs for rare illnesses — advocate”.31 The agency’s success at reducing the cost of medications is portrayed as cruelly quantifying and disregarding human suffering.
(2) Pharmac’s “outdated” schedule
According to the critics of Pharmac, New Zealand is hopelessly behind the times. Compared to other OECD countries, New Zealand is consistently slow to fund new medications. In a report funded by Medicines New Zealand (a pharmaceutical lobby group), New Zealand ranks last of 20 comparable OECD countries for funding new molecular entities (NMEs).32 Moreover, New Zealand lags behind most comparable OECD nations in the number of modern medicines it funds.33 In addition to published reports,
mainstream media has also picked up these criticisms.34 For example, New Zealand has been negatively compared to Australia as being far slower to fund new medicines.35
C Political forces
The interest groups applying the most pressure on the government are disease interest groups and pharmaceutical lobbies. It is no secret that the pharmaceutical industry is opposed to Pharmac. In addition to publishing negative reports of Pharmac’s performance, pharmaceutical companies have filed multiple unsuccessful legal challenges under the Commerce Act 1986 for anticompetitive practices.36 More recently, there was pressure on the New Zealand Government during negotiations of the Trans-Pacific Partnership free trade agreement, where American pharmaceutical interests sought Pharmac’s disestablishment.37
These groups have successfully brought about the review, and arguably influenced the reforms. Although these groups may have radically different motives, they want the same outcome—to divert public funds to their interests, particularly the funding of expensive treatments for rare diseases. An illustration of these common interests is Janssen Biotech, the pharmaceutical maker of ustekinumab, donating money to Crohn’s and Colitis NZ, who raised the petition for ustekinumab.38 This point might seem conspiratorial and fanciful. However, I will illustrate that the Government has capitulated to these types of demands before.
IV Case Studies
The first two case studies are the only examples where the Government directly overruled a Pharmac decision. The later cases are current examples of Pharmac refusing to fund. However, as will later be discussed the review and its consequences have now led to funding of these two medications.
A Interferon beta for multiple sclerosis
On 26 December 1999, the newly elected Labour-led government announced its decision to fund interferon beta drugs directly.39 Interferon beta is a treatment for multiple sclerosis (MS), a debilitating neurological condition. Pharmac had reviewed the treatment twice and
<www.stuff.co.nz>; Robbie Nicol and Finnius Teppett “The comically large catch in the Government’s review into Pharmac” (3 May 2021) Stuff <www.stuff.co.nz>; Zane Small “Jacinda Ardern: Not fair to compare Pharmac with Australia’s system” (5 February 2019) Newshub
<www.newshub.co.nz>; Penny Tucker “Pharmac works well. Unless you’re sick” (2 June 2021) Stuff <www.stuff.co.nz>; and Breast Cancer Foundation NZ “Pharmac review a chance to end agonisingly slow drug approval process” (13 October 2020)
<www.breastcancerfoundation.org.nz>.
concluded that the evidence did not reliably establish a benefit for MS patients that justified the cost.40 The treatment was expensive, costing over $14,000 annually per patient for a total of over $5 million.41 The decision to ignore the advice of Pharmac was based on an earlier election promise by Labour.42 During the 1999 election, a well- organised disease interest group, the MS Society, and clinical experts convinced Labour to promise to fund the drug if elected. Most likely, the decision for Labour to support this cause was motivated by the need to win popular support during a political campaign.
B Herceptin for breast cancer
In 2008, the newly elected National-led Government announced it would increase the treatment period for Herceptin from nine weeks to 12 months.43 Herceptin is a treatment for HER2, an aggressive form of breast cancer. In July 2006, Pharmac and district health boards declined to fund the 12-month sequential treatment because there was insufficient evidence to support its efficacy over the nine-week concurrent regimen.44 Like interferon beta, a group of patients wanted Herceptin, who the media dubbed the “Herceptin Heroines”.45 The Heroines even made an unsuccessful judicial review application for Pharmac’s decision.46 During National’s election campaign, they promised to fund Herceptin if elected, which they did.47
C Spinraza for spinal muscular atrophy
Spinal muscular atrophy (SMA) is a genetic condition that affects the body’s ability to create muscle. Those who suffer from the condition are physically disabled and have significantly reduced life expectancy. Spinraza is a new treatment with promising results and is viewed by those who suffer from SMA as their best chance to live.48 Pharmac had declined to fund this treatment in New Zealand.49 The cost–utility analysis has shown the high cost of the medication cannot be justified by its clinical benefits.50 Disease interest groups have been very critical of this decision. However, it is arguable that these criticisms were part of the reason for the current review.51
D Ustekinumab for Crohn’s disease
Crohn’s disease is an inflammatory bowel disease (IBD).52 It causes a broad range of unpleasant symptoms for sufferers that can significantly reduce their quality of life.53 Crohn’s is difficult to treat because even the best medications are not guaranteed to succeed, and most treatments have long-term side effects.54 Consequently, for many IBD sufferers, treatment involves trialling available medications hoping that one will work.55 Ustekinumab is a new biologic treatment that could help patients who have exhausted all available treatments.56 Unfortunately, like other biologic treatments, it is very expensive.57 Prior to the review and its changes, Pharmac had declined to fund it because there are other similar medications available. Like for Spinraza and SMA, there is an active disease interest group.
V Application of Public Choice Theory
A Theoretical lens
Public choice theory is the economic analysis of political institutions and actors. Public choice is the “application of the principles of maximizing behavior and demand and supply to institutions and behavior in the political world”.58
In the field of public choice, there is a theory known as interest group approach.59 It argues that political changes are driven by interest groups who seek to redistribute wealth.60 Politics is a “market for wealth redistribution”, and “participants are self- interested politicians and citizens”.61 Nearly all political decisions can be viewed as allocations of wealth. Taxation policies or even public amenities such as parks will allocate more or fewer resources to particular citizens. In these wealth transfers, politicians act as middlemen and are paid with votes, positive public support and campaign contributions.62 It will be efficient for a “buyer” (an interest group) to pay for government intervention where the payment to the politician is less than the benefit of the intervention.63 For example, it will be efficient for a lobbyist to pay a $100,000 donation to a politician if there is a corresponding tax cut of $150,000. The supplier is the section of the population that has resources taken by government intervention.64 It will be efficient for the supplier to resist government intervention where the cost of resisting is less than the proposed
53 At 111.
intervention.65 For example, it would be efficient for a lobby to allow a wealth transfer through a new tax to occur if the cost of paying the politician to prevent transfer is greater than the tax liability.
The benefits secured extend beyond taxation and include laws that would effectively exclude competitors from a market or secure public funding for projects. The costs of resistance include any information costs. Information costs play a significant part on both sides of the transaction because many groups may be unaware that they are subject to a beneficial or negative transfer.66 Generally, it will be easier for smaller interest groups (for example, pharmaceutical lobby groups or a disease interest group) to form and effect a wealth transfer because the information cost will be lower.67 Information cost varies depending on the relative information of the actors:68
Several possibilities are relevant in this regard: (1) The winners [those who benefit from a wealth transfer] and losers [those who suffer from a wealth transfer] on an issue are well identified and know who each other are; (2) the winners and losers are not easily identified, either to themselves or to each other; (3) obviously, winners can be easily identified while losers cannot, and conversely.
For disease interest groups, the last possibility is most common because each sufferer of a disease, or family member of such person, can self-identify as winner and readily identify other disease suffers. The losers are society at large, who must bear the cost of a transfer either by paying increased taxes or having that money not used elsewhere. Given the size of the loser group and inherent difficulty in identifying the exact nature of their loss they have a much higher information cost. Consequently, it will be less likely that a large interest group (such as all taxpayers) will resist a wealth transfer because the organisational and informational costs are much higher. Politicians maximise their gains “by transferring wealth from combinations of citizens who resist the least to those who value transfers the most”.69
Importantly, this market of wealth distribution may not increase the overall social welfare but reduce it by inefficiently allocating resources—for example, a cartel of cobblers who petition to manufacture government-issued shoes exclusively. The cartel pays a sizeable contribution to a political party, ensuring their re-election and securing the exclusive dealing. As a result of the arrangement, cheaper and more efficient cobblers do not produce shoes. Consequently, the overall efficiency is reduced due to an interest group securing a rent.70
There is a long history of interest groups seeking rents or favourable government interventions in public health policies. For example, the prohibition movement and laws in the United States demonstrate how two different interest groups, the bootleggers and Baptists, benefited from and sought the same outcome. The Baptists were motivated by
68 At 17.
moral and religious virtue.71 They sought to improve the health and moral character of citizens by prohibiting alcohol. The bootleggers were financially motivated—they sought to exclude legitimate alcohol manufacturers from the market via prohibition.72 This alliance between commercial and moralistic interests has been termed the “bootleggers and Baptists” phenomenon and has been observed in other similar contexts.73 In many cases, it is the combination of commercial and moralistic interests that make a government intervention possible. It is necessary to have both a virtuous interest group and another financially motivated one.
B Application
(1) Case-studies failures and successes: pre-review
Why did the MS society and Breast Cancer Society succeed in effecting Government intervention where the Crohn’s and Colitis Society and SMA Society, at least initially, failed? Arguably, the success of these two interest groups can be attributed to their ability to “pay” the politicians to make such changes. There are some notable similarities between the two success cases that are not shared with the failed cases.
First, both interventions occurred during an election campaign.74 For the politicians who made those election promises, there was an increased demand to secure popular support. The successful lobbying groups had accrued public backing, and the politicians wanted to take advantage of this.
Secondly, in both cases, the election promises were made by opposition parties. Since these parties were not in Government, overruling a decision of Pharmac could not be viewed as a personal failing in their governance. Moreover, they would be less concerned about wealth transfer because they were not managing the treasury budget. As one key informant remarked in a study, “[y]ou hate it in Opposition and you love it when you go on the Treasury bench.”75
In terms of interest group theory, the supplier is the general population paying taxes. Consequently, there is not a well-organised interest opposing this wealth transfer. For politicians, the concern for these general wealth transfers will be in maintaining an effective budget, such as keeping taxes lower and reducing government debt and spending. As the management of the budget rests with the incumbent Government, budgetary failures are more concerning for them than for an opposition party. Therefore, in cases where no well-organised group opposes a wealth transfer, an opposition party is more likely to promise such a transfer than an incumbent Government.
Thirdly, the Herceptin Heroines were well-funded because they had sufficient resources to mount a judicial review application in the Courts.76 Being well-funded enables an interest group to market its message more effectively.
Fourthly, it was important that the successful examples were serious diseases and were even terminal. The severity of a disease will correlate to the amount of public support
that the disease can gather.77 Greater public support will be more enticing for a politician because it casts them in a sympathetic light.
Finally, a part of the success of these campaigns could be attributed to the “bootlegger and Baptist” phenomenon. The combination of the moral virtue of the disease interest groups and the pharmacies’ financial resources makes the intervention possible. It may have been that at the time pharmaceutical companies might have directly funded the “Baptists” (that is, the disease interests groups). For example, when Medicines New Zealand created a $150,000 fund for their “Election 2017 project”, which promoted the creation of an interim drug fund and increased funding of emerging medicines.78 However, direct collusion, cooperation or coordination may not always be present and the phenomenon is still applicable when these two different groups work in tandem to effect the same end.
(2) Motivations of interest groups
Interest group theory can also explain why pharmaceutical and disease interest groups seek to change Pharmac’s policy or decisions. As a buyer in the market, it will be most efficient for disease interest groups to have the government pay for the medications rather than themselves. As interest theory group states, it will only be rational for the buyer to procure public funds where the cost of doing so is less than the benefit. In these cases, the cost of the medications is extremely high, so the benefit of the government purchasing the drugs is very high. In comparison, the cost of lobbying is low, and personally funding the medications is very high. This breakdown of benefits and costs explains why the lobby groups tend to advocate for very costly medications.
For pharmaceutical lobbyists, the potential profit from these medications is high. It is efficient for buyers to spend significant amounts of money lobbying to get medications added to the Schedule. Companies benefit from being on the Schedule because Pharmac is a monopsony, so they benefit from a lack of competition. They are essentially guaranteed a reasonable amount of market share.
Strangely, the motivation to criticise and change Pharmac will correlate to how successful Pharmac is in managing the Schedule. An optimised schedule will mean the fewest number of funded drugs because it is best to reduce redundancy in treatments.79 This efficiency causes a loss for pharmaceutical companies because they do not have their entire range of treatments funded. It also causes a loss to patients who have exhausted the entire range of available medications. The cost savings that Pharmac is so good at are a wealth transfer from pharmaceutical companies and untreatable patients to New Zealand taxpayers and those who receive effective medical treatment from the Schedule.80
(3) Pharmac’s stability
This characterisation of the wealth transfer helps to explain the stability of Pharmac. It is remarkable that in the 28 years that Pharmac has existed (prior to the review), it has only been overruled twice. As mentioned earlier, the political gain to overrule Pharmac is weakest when a party is in Government. Politicians want to keep the broadest support possible, and Pharmac helps to do this. If the general public is the “supplier” who the pharmaceutical industry is attempting to ‘buy’ from, there will be significant resistance to this. Politicians will only favour the transfer of wealth where the resistance is less than the payment for the intervention. Pharmac is a mechanism to prevent the transfer and therefore protects the general public. Not only does it prevent wealth transfer, but it is also a more efficient system and thus creates more overall social welfare. Two pieces of research support this conclusion.
First, Rajan Ragupathy and others conducted a series of interviews with key players in the management and operation of Pharmac on their perspectives.81 The interviewees included senior staff at Pharmac, medical experts, pharmaceutical industry members and, importantly, Members of Parliament.82 The interviewees were generally positive about Pharmac. Some key points were that Pharmac was very good at reducing costs, and its political stability and independence comes from cross-party political support.83 The views of these Members of Parliament demonstrate an awareness of the value that Pharmac brings in managing the budget, thereby protecting the interests of New Zealand’s taxpayers.
Interestingly, the National-led government that introduced the 12-month treatment of Herceptin subsequently admitted that it was wrong of them to have overruled Pharmac. Health Minister the Hon Dr Jonathan Coleman conceded that overriding Pharmac turned it into a “political football”.84 This view reinforces the point that politicians understand Pharmac’s value and are generally unwilling to override decisions once in power.
Secondly, Linda Yamoah and others conducted a survey gathering the views of New Zealanders on health-related values.85 The survey asked participants to rank 13 different values, including disease-related values (rarity and severity of disease) and drug-related values (the ability of the drug to work and potential to extend life).86 The participants were also surveyed on several trade-off scenarios, which questions how to allocate limited resources (whether to fund a drug to treat a common disease or another drug for a rare disease.)87 The survey found that the most important values were the drug’s ability to improve the quality and quantity of life, the drug’s ability to work and the severity of the disease.88 Moreover, in the trade-off scenarios, the participants favoured spending more money on treating common diseases and even preferred putting money to other uses rather than treating rare diseases.89 The conclusion that can be drawn from these findings is that the general public’s values are broadly aligned with the processes of Pharmac. Furthermore, the preference for spending money on other things rather than rare
89 At 116.
diseases is direct evidence that the public is concerned with a wealth transfer to the pharmaceutical company and prefers efficient spending.
VI Defending Pharmac
Having explored the various motivations of interest groups, I will now argue that some of the criticisms of Pharmac either do not hold much weight or are an attempt by interest groups to secure favourable wealth transfers. Ultimately, I argue that the influences of these interest groups should be resisted, and we should preserve Pharmac’s apolitical status.
A Responding to the criticisms
(1) Failure to fund particular treatments
Broadly, there are two ways for Pharmac to be unjustified in rejecting funding for treatments like Spinraza and ustekinumab. The first way would be if Pharmac had not assessed the relevant evidence against the current criteria used to evaluate medications. However, this would appear unlikely because Pharmac draws from a wealth of expert experience and knowledge when making determinations.90 This article is not the place to challenge Pharmac’s empirical findings, so it will be assumed on reasonable grounds that there has been no error.
The second way that Pharmac might be unjustified would be if its methodology was flawed. As earlier mentioned, Pharmac broadly employs a utilitarian analysis of the benefits of a particular medication. Perhaps we should not make health decisions on this basis. Instead, where treatment exists that can save an individual’s life, such as with Spinraza, we might be obligated to pay for such a treatment. Fiona Tolich sums up this sentiment in her statement, “[w]hy would you pick kids with cancer to live and pick kids with SMA to die”?91
Arguably, disease interest groups play an important role in identifying cases where funding is needed to save lives to the public. Pharmac should be adjusted to take into consideration life-threatening health conditions and public support for treatments. Unless the budget for Pharmac is increased, which has been excluded from the review, these changes would be the only way for these treatments to be funded.
As appealing as these changes might appear to be, there are significant issues with them. There is a limited resource pool to purchase pharmaceuticals. Any purchases will come with the cost that the resource has not been used for another purchase—the opportunity cost.92 Choosing to fund Spinraza will come with the opportunity cost that another medication that might save a life is not funded. There is always going to be a trade- off between people’s lives in these decisions; that is, a wealth transfer. Consequently, as unfair and regrettable as it might appear that we as a country do not take every measure available to save the lives of those suffering from SMA, there is a justified reason for why because we spend resources elsewhere, namely to save other lives. Fundamentally, an
objection that someone will die or suffer because a medication is not funded, albeit tragic and heartbreaking, is not a good reason alone to overrule Pharmac’s decision or change its criteria.
Similarly, Pharmac should not give more weight to treatments that receive public support. That would allow a wealth transfer from those with funded medications to those with unfunded medications with sufficient public support. Such a system would be a popularity contest to determine who lives and dies, which is far less fair than the current system. Therefore, Pharmac should continue to apply the current criteria and act independently when determining the funding of particular treatments.
(2) “Outdated” Pharmac schedule
The criticism that Pharmac is “outdated” stems from two issues. First is the timeliness issue. Comparatively, New Zealand is slow to adopt new medications. Secondly, New Zealand has an older and narrower range of medications compared to other developed countries.
Pharmac has responded to these concerns about its “outdated” Schedule. The answer to this criticism is that assessing New Zealand by the novelty and quantity of medications in our range of treatments is a poor metric by which to assess our health outcomes.93 New Zealand is often slow to adopt a new medication because there is limited evidence to support its efficacy, or there is an existing range of treatments for the same condition.94 New treatments are often very costly relative to current treatments and their efficacy.
A more relevant concern about Pharmac’s “outdated” Schedule arises from a desire for static efficiency.95 The concern is that Pharmac is attempting to maximise gains from the limited budget for the present and immediate future.96 Consequently, Pharmac might be less efficient because it is not funding medications that would provide greater long- term benefits. However, it is possible that the underfunding of medications that might result in long term benefits is merely a product of Pharmac’s limited budget. Pharmac might not be valuing current benefits greater than long-term benefits but rather with the funds able is making the best investments possible, which happens to be the short-term benefits. Hopefully, the Pharmac review will determine whether there is an inefficient preference for shorter-term benefits.
Lastly, it needs to be acknowledged that the pharmaceutical companies’ criticism of Pharmac’s “outdated” Schedule has a clear financial motive. Funding more and newer medications would result in higher revenue for these companies. Caution is needed when reviewing this aspect of Pharmac’s processes because of the risk of a wealth transfer from the New Zealand taxpayers to the pharmaceutical companies.
B Possible improvements
This article has discussed the strengths of Pharmac and defended it from its main critics. There are, however, areas of improvement, some of which the review does identify (as discussed later). One potential change to Pharmac might improve the current system and may also impact its independence and effectiveness—increased transparency.
Pharmac has often been secretive about its processes. For example, Pharmac has declined to release its cost–utility analysis and expected QALYs per million for medications.97 This lack of transparency has caused frustration for experts who wish to analyse and perhaps show an error in Pharmac’s assessment.98 Moreover, it has been demoralising for patients not to know the full reasons why a life-saving medication has not been funded.99 Increased transparency could resolve these issues. Experts would be able to provide more effective feedback and criticism or be more confident that Pharmac has reached a reasonable decision. For patients, this measure might provide some closure.
However, transparency could come with a steep cost and should be limited in its scope. Increased transparency has two distinct risks. First, it might impact Pharmac’s ability to negotiate with pharmaceutical companies effectively. Pharmac’s most closely guarded secret is its priority list, which ranks medications in order of most needed to least needed.100 If this information were publicly available, it would undermine Pharmac’s bargaining position as pharmaceutical companies would know which medications are most important and could raise their prices. Therefore, transparency might be needed to be limited to the extent that it could affect commercially sensitive information.
The second risk is that greater transparency might allow interest groups to apply more pressure to politicians. With increased transparency will come greater scrutiny of Pharmac’s decisions. Scrutiny will help to ensure that Pharmac is making decisions without error. However, if some errors or decisions are contestable, then the pressure will be on politicians to correct these errors. Transparency may amount to political oversight of Pharmac decisions. If political oversight is the natural response to increased transparency, this could increase activity and successes for disease interest groups in overturning Pharmac decisions.
My recommendation is that with increased transparency, there should be an external non-political body to oversee and correct any potential errors in Pharmac’s decisions or processes. Overseas research has indicated a link between politicians “earmarking” funds towards particular diseases and an increase in government spending on pharmaceuticals.101 Introducing transparency and political intervention will arguably have the same earmarking issues in New Zealand if we do not ensure separate apolitical oversight. Any earmarks on Pharmac’s funds would likely be a less efficient allocation of resources than Pharmac’s rigorous processes. Therefore, to promote efficiency and prevent wealth transfers, it is crucial that Pharmac does not become a political football.
VII The Review
The Pharmac review was finalised in February 2022.102 The review was critical of Pharmac. The prominent areas of criticism were inequitable health outcomes and poor internal systems, resulting in Pharmac inconsistently applying its own standards and processes in reaching decisions.103 The inequities resulted in Māori, Pasifika and disabled persons having poorer access to medications.104 These are not acceptable outcomes. Equitable results are crucial. Efficiency is an incredibly important directive of Pharmac, the greater savings that can be made mean other medications can be funded and more lives saved. However, efficiency cannot be the sole objective, and Pharmac should have been trading- off efficiency in maximising QALYs for a more equitable distribution of QALYs.105 The author welcomes the reforms in these areas.The final area of note from the report were the findings on the rare diseases (or rare disorders as the report refers to them).106 The report recommended that more medications to treat rare diseases be funded, making the following remarks:107
... if we do want to fund more of these medicines, consideration needs to be given to where in the general appropriation for health this money will come from. There is no easy way forward and so the suggestions we make are a pragmatic extension of what Pharmac currently does.
The report also recommended the formation of a rare disorder strategy, the creation of a rare disorders advisory committee within Pharmac and the involvement of the lived experience of patients with rare disorders in the decision-making process.108
Following the review, the Labour Government announced a significant $191 million boost to the Pharmac budget, an increase of approximately 20 per cent.109 A range of further medications were funded. Notably this included Spinraza and ustekinumab.110 The funding of these medications and overall increase to the budget can be viewed as “wins” for the pharmaceutical lobbyists and rare disease interest groups who have succeeded in obtaining favourable reforms. The life-changing, newly funded medications will have a significant positive impact for affected New Zealanders. However, these wins may have come at others’ loss. It may be that the most efficient QALYs were obtained when these medications were funded. Or, it may be that a less efficient decision was made but that the politicians were “paid” to make it happen. Either way the political pressure resulting from a critical review meant that, as with the funding of Herceptin and interferon beta, politicians stood to gain political capital by increasing funding.
VIII Conclusion
Pharmac has unquestionably succeeded in saving New Zealand a considerable amount of pharmaceutical spending and expanding the available medicines to New Zealanders. The critics of Pharmac, especially those who suffer from a serious illness, do deserve our sympathy. Life has been cruel and unfair to rob them of their health. The recent further funding of medications like Spinraza and ustekinumab will improve their lives. But one clear cost associated with the funding is the structural change that Pharmac will undergo in the foreseeable future. The extent to which the remarkable features that made Pharmac so effective will be retained remains to be seen. As the then Minister of Health, the Hon Andrew Little, stated following the review, “[t]he days of the independent republic of Pharmac are over.”111 Some of the changes to Pharmac will be for the better, but there is a risk that we may lose what has made the agency so effective. It is important to be wary of the risk that Pharmac’s loss of independence may render it a political football.This article started with how Pharmac saved my life. Funding my life-saving medication was only possible by the rigorous and careful allocation of Pharmac’s budget. It is easy to criticise Pharmac with emotive stories. But stories like mine demonstrate the enormous good that Pharmac has done, a sentiment which is easy to forget.
This article has shown that some of the common criticisms of Pharmac do not hold up. The solution to the issues raised in this article, such as a lack of funding for new medications, does not lie with changing Pharmac but with increasing their budget. Pharmac’s successes will only continue if it remains apolitical.
NZLII:
Copyright Policy
|
Disclaimers
|
Privacy Policy
|
Feedback
URL: http://www.nzlii.org/nz/journals/NZPubIntLawJl/2023/3.html