AustLII Home | Databases | WorldLII | Search | Feedback

Queensland University of Technology Law and Justice Journal

Queesland University of Technology Law and Justice Journal (QUTLJJ)
You are here:  AustLII >> Databases >> Queensland University of Technology Law and Justice Journal >> 2003 >> [2003] QUTLawJJl 3

Database Search | Name Search | Recent Articles | Noteup | LawCite | Author Info | Download | Help

Eagles, Ian; Longdin, Louise --- "Competition in Information and Computer Technology Markets: Intellectual Prtoperty Licensing and s 51(3) of the Trade Practices Act 1974 (2003)" [2003] QUTLawJJl 3; (2003) 3(1) Queensland University of Technology Law and Justice Journal 28

Competition In Information And Computer Technology Markets: Intellectual Property Licensing And Section 51(3) Of The Trade Practices Act 1974

IAN EAGLES[*] AND LOUISE LONGDIN[**]

I INTRODUCTION

Intellectual property licensing[1] presents competition lawyers and regulators with something of a puzzle. The practice is both pervasive and necessary and yet will often take forms which on their face appear to run foul of the sometimes broadly expressed prohibitions through which most jurisdictions enact their competition policy. While most of these prohibitions have long been tamed into rules of reason, they can, as currently in Australia still induce panic (a panic largely borne of confusion)[2] in right holders and licensees who confront them for the first time. Panic rises to even higher levels when intellectual property owners are threatened with the sudden removal of the statutory shield which up until now has protected most (but significantly not all) of their dealings with licensees from the attention of regulators and competitors. Feeling more than usually exposed by this proposed legislative disarmament are suppliers of computer software and other forms of information and communications technology, accustomed as they have been to the steady expansion of legal protection[3] (the lifting of parallel importation restrictions being one of the rare examples of retreat)[4] rather than the contraction they wrongly assume to be imminent unless fended off by intensive lobbying.[5] How justified are these fears? For the most part, not very. Only where the Trade Practices Act 1974 imposes per se liability do the lobbyists have a case and here the proposed changes improve the position of right holders rather than the contrary. Indeed if there is a criticism to be made of the suggestions of the Intellectual Property and Competition Law Review Committee’s (the ‘Ergas Committee’) in its Review of Intellectual Property Legislation under the Competition Principles Agreement[6] and the government’s response to them (‘Government Response’)[7] is that the changes are prompted by long standing problems with the whole of Part IV itself (still under review at the time of writing).

II THE PRESENT STATE OF THE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY INTERFACE IN TRADE PRACTICES LAW

There are a number of exemptions to the raft of practices prohibited by Part IV of the TPA. Section 51(1) of the Act states in general terms that in deciding whether a person has contravened Part IV certain matters must be disregarded. These are ‘anything specified in, and specifically authorised by an Act (not including an Act relating to patents, trademarks, designs or copyrights) or regulations made under such an Act.’ Standing alone, this would mean that many dealings in intellectual property would be left unprotected against competition scrutiny. However, what the legislature took with its s 51(1) hand, it largely returns with its s 51(3) hand. The latter provision proceeds, albeit ambiguously, to provide a wide (if not unlimited) protection for intellectual property owners and their licensees. Section 51(3) protects the imposing or giving effect to conditions contained in licences and assignments to the extent that those conditions relate to the subject matter of the intellectual property statute in question. Where trademarks are concerned, the exemption is expressly limited to conditions that relate to the kinds, qualities and standards of goods bearing the mark.[8]

Section 51(3) is not a blanket exemption for all licences or assignments of intellectual property rights. It does not cover practices which infringe s 46 (misuse of market power); s 46A (misuse of market power in a Trans-Tasman market) or s 48 (resale price maintenance). The exemption extends only to conditions contained in or effected by licences or assignments which might otherwise be construed as one of the following anti-competitive practices:

Putting aside for the moment the question whether intellectual property rights require this special treatment, the present s 51(3) is flawed even on its own terms. First the use of the nebulous ‘relates to’ (surely the vaguest and most open ended verb in the drafting tool box) to link right and exemption positively invites parties to expand the scope of the protection thus offered by sprinkling the same ambiguous terminology indiscriminately throughout their licences and assignments. Second, if there are sound policy reasons for leaving particular categories of rights and particular types of breach outside the protective umbrella of s 51(3) these have never been adequately articulated, much less defended.

A ‘Relates To’ and the Scope of Grant Problem

Most competition regimes around the world, when faced with the problem of how to treat intellectual property, take as their starting point an inquiry into the exact nature of the exclusive rights conferred on patent, copyright, trademark owners under national law: What is it that owners are allowed to do, prevent others from doing or licence those others to do? Actions within the four walls of the right are then given varying degrees of special treatment in the ensuing competition analysis. This approach, usually described as a ‘scope of the grant’ inquiry,[12] is intended to provide judges and regulators in jurisdictions which have no statutory exemptions for intellectual property with a rebuttable presumption of validity for actions by right holders which do not go beyond the bounds of whatever it is that the state has granted to them. Those who cannot bring themselves within these bounds have something to explain. For those who can, the onus remains on their opponent (be it competitor or regulator) to demonstrate anticompetitive intent or outcome.[13] In these jurisdictions it is the first part of a two part test. For jurisdictions like Australia which choose to regulate the competition law/intellectual property interface by statute, ‘scope of grant’ ceases to be purely evidentiary in its application and instead is used as a one step substantive test with which to divide applicants into saved saints who escape liability entirely and potential sinners to be subjected to the full rigours of an ordinary Part IV analysis. This is not the purpose for which the ‘scope of grant’ test was designed. Even if it were, it is not obvious from its terms that s 51(3) encapsulates the scope of grant test in any form that its European and American proponents would recognise. Nor has judicial exegesis illuminated what the drafters have left unclear. In Transfield Pty Ltd v Arlo International[14] two different interpretations of ‘relates to’ were provided by the High Court. On one view, that of Barwick CJ and Wilson J, the exception would extend to the terms of any licence or assignment as long as there is some nexus with the intellectual property right in question. Thus, irrespective of their impact on competition, exclusive licensing, price, quantity and territorial constraints would not infringe Part IV. On another view, that of Mason J, the scope of the restrictions right holders may properly impose on their licensees or assignees would not extend to gaining an advantage ‘collateral’ to those enjoyed directly under the grant of the right, a judicial nod in the direction of ‘scope of grant.’ [15]

B Unprotected Rights and Dealings

As it currently stands s 51(3) does not extend to rights whose only protection is at common law or equity. These include:

These omissions are deliberate, presumably on the grounds that non statutory rights are less certain in scope and application than ‘true’ intellectual property rights.[16] The absence of any reference to plant breeders’ rights in s 51(3) on the other hand seems to be due to a failure to monitor and update within the bureaucracy.[17]

Another problem with s 51(3) in its present form is that it is inconsistent in its treatment of even the rights it does list. Assignments of patents, copyrights and registered designs are covered but the assignment of trade marks is left unprotected.

C Non Exempt Breaches

At present s 51(3) provides no protection for actual or putative transgression under s 46 (misuse of market power) or s 48 (resale price maintenance). This puts refusals to licence and attempts to control the price of licensed products (or spare parts for those products) at risk.

III THE CHANGES PROPOSED BY THE ERGAS COMMITTEE

The Ergas Committee is not the first consultative body to grapple with s 51(3). The National Competition Council had earlier recommended that it be retained but amended so as to remove horizontal dealings and price and quantity restrictions from its ambit.[18] This was not the road down which the Ergas Committee chose to go. Instead it took the view that:

[Intellectual property statutes confer] upon the intellectual property right holder a series of exclusive privileges designed to promote innovation. Given that those rights are conferred by legislation, they should be able to be effectively exercised even when this involves (as it generally must) the exclusion of others. However, these rights should not be capable of being used to go beyond the market power those rights directly confer. That is the right holder should not be allowed to extend the statutory right into a wider right of exclusion with the effect of substantially lessening competition. [original emphasis supplied] [19]

To this end the Committee suggested both widening and narrowing the protection currently provided by repealing the existing s 51(3) and replacing it with a provision which would:

What is envisaged here is a test which, although two step like its American and European progenitors, is substantive rather than evidentiary and would apply across the whole of Part IV. The second step in that test, the substantial lessening of competition override, is both workable (once supplemented by guidelines) and defensible to all sides of the debate currently raging among law and economics scholars as to how competition policy and intellectual property should interact in a modern economy.[20] It sensibly avoids the wilder shores of theory without unduly hobbling the regulator or subjecting owners, assignees and licensees to avoidable transaction costs. It is the first part of the two step test which causes difficulty on both conceptual and practical grounds. As regards the latter, the decision to retain the unsatisfactory ‘relates’ to set the parameters of exemption is simply to invite keen legal minds to endlessly parse the Transfield judgment in the interests of their clients until the High Court definitely opts for one interpretation over another. If it was intended to enact the scope of grant principle why not select language more suited to the task?[21]

But why did the Ergas Committee assume that the task has to be undertaken at all? Did they intend it to be a way of distinguishing between market power which is external to the right (and thus unprotected) and the power deriving directly from the right (which is assumed to be unassailable). If this was the Committee’s intention then the two step test cannot work as they describe it because their substantial lessening of competition override makes no such distinction. Nor could it. Intellectual property rights may sustain market power derived from other sources without themselves creating that power, a point forcibly made by the seven strong Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia (‘DC Circuit’) in United States v Microsoft Corp.[22] In that case the defendant Microsoft had claimed that its intellectual property in its software gave it overarching power to use that property howsoever it wished and legally justified the entire raft of anticompetitive provisions contained in its licensing arrangements with original computer equipment makers. The DC Circuit brushed off this broad (and, in its view, frivolous) argument as ‘no more correct than the proposition that use of one’s personal property, such as a baseball bat, cannot give rise to tort liability’.[23]

If the boundaries of the right do not set the limits of liability why write them into the statute at all? They could of course be used as an evidentiary tool for resisting a finding of anti-competitive purpose but since the Committee rejects purpose tests this cannot be the explanation. The reason, one suspects, is to be found in their perceptive analysis of Part IV as a whole. While they concede that it was not their task to comment on, or seek amendment to, the wider provisions of the Act[24] they clearly felt uncomfortable both with the forms of business behaviour selected for per se proscription in Part IV[25] and the overall emphasis on enumerating practices even within those parts of the Act which proceed by way of rule of reason analysis.[26] The Committee was obviously sceptical about the degree to which any practice could be assumed to exploit consumers and lessen competition without further inquiry and thought intellectual practices particularly vulnerable to this way of thinking given its non rivalrous nature and the importance of licensing to its successful exploitation. The Committee’s aim seems therefore to have been to remove intellectual property rights to a place of greater safety until such time as the rest of Part IV is overhauled, a job which they allow was outside their brief.[27] The scope of grant principle is there to provide the walls of this temporary sanctuary.

The difficulty with this approach is that it anticipates outcomes for the wider reform process which are far from assured. Are we really likely to see a Part IV entirely shorn of per se provisions (horizontal price fixing included) and purpose tests? If these things did not happen Australia would, if the Ergas proposals were enacted, be left with a competition regime which permanently treats intellectual property very differently from other rights, thus departing from the principle of neutrality encapsulated in the Microsoft judgment. As to the grounds on which such departures might be justified the Committee suggests three:

As to the first, absolute certainty means either absolute exemption or per se liability. As the American experience shows, the economic rationality which the rule of reason is meant to deliver carries its own uncertainty price tag as competing theories fight it out in the courts and the commentary. Relative certainty is obtainable only by guidelines. It cannot be legislated. Nor is it obvious that the absence of a special statutory regime for intellectual property in the United States or the European Union unduly inhibits investment in intellectual property licences in those jurisdictions.

As to the second, it is the proposed guidelines which will prevent mobs of apprehensive owners and licensees beating a path to the ACCC’s door. Writing the scope of grant principle into the statute will do nothing to beat them back (especially while its operation continues to be made uncertain by the ‘relates to’ terminology).

The third ground does have more force but the answer lies in education. The transition can either be effected or delayed until after the Dawson Committee reports and the legislative fate of its recommendations is clear. There is no obvious case for a temporary via media to lessen a pain which must eventually be suffered.

These are minor cavils, however. Taken in the round, the Ergas Committee’s proposals are a thoughtful and well reasoned response to the problems of integrating intellectual property and competition policy. Given that their hands were largely tied by having to work within the existing ss 45, 47 and 48, the Committee’s recommendations would, if enacted, have been a vast improvement on the present position. The same, alas, cannot be said of the Government’s sketchy and conceptually incoherent response.

IV THE GOVERNMENT RESPONSE

While the Government Response endorses the need for intellectual property rights to be given distinctive treatment under Part IV there is little sign that this is based on any deep understanding of what led the Ergas Committee to adopt this stance. Worse, it introduces further layers of complexity to an already convoluted s 51(3) on the basis of policy distinctions which it fails to state, much less explain. As outlined to date, the government’s intentions are to bring intellectual property licensing in general under Part IV but retain s 51(3) in some form to deal with the problems raised by the existing per se provisions in ss 45, 45A, 47 and 4D, that is those concerned with horizontal price fixing, third line forcing and exclusionary boycotts. This residual exemption would then be subject to a substantial lessening of competition test. By inference this override would not need to apply to the ‘purpose and effect’ rules of reason in the rest of ss 45 and 47 because they already require the application of such a test. (A crucial departure from Ergas which may not have been fully thought through.) One of the perhaps unintended consequences would be that licensing practices intended to bring about an anti-competitive outcome could continue to be at risk irrespective of whatever outcome was achieved or even achievable. The residual s 51(3) would seemingly not apply to breaches of ss 46, 46A and, importantly for this discussion, the resale price maintenance provision in s 48. Whether the government would retain the shapeless ‘relates to’ is as yet unclear.

Where does this lead the scope of grant principle? It would have no relevance to the rule of reason provisions in ss 45 and 47. Licence terms attacked under these sections would neither be less vulnerable within grant or more vulnerable outside it. Scope of grant would be equally irrelevant to the operation of s 48. Once the terms of s 48 were met and the supply of goods or services withheld or threatened to be withheld liability would attach without any need for an inquiry into the boundaries of the right being licensed. Only in relation to third line forcing, horizontal price fixing and exclusionary boycotts would scope of grant continue to matter. In these cases, practices outside the grant would not have the benefit of the proposed substantial lessening of competition override.

What is puzzling about the choices the government has made here is that they do not seem to be based on an evaluation of the content and scope of existing per se rules (whether in general terms or as applied in intellectual property licences). Given that all of these breaches are now authorisable the continued relegation of resale price maintenance to the licensing sin bin needs explanation. (Horizontal price fixing would be a better candidate, if one were needed, there being few economists willing to find glimmers of pro-competitive gold among its universally conceded anti-competitive dross.)

Considerably less controversial is the government’s decision to include plant breeders’ rights within the residual exemption and to continue existing protections for licences and arrangements entered into before any amendments take effect. The role and mode of operation of the guidelines is also spelt out in more detail in the Government Response than in the Ergas Committee’s Report. This detail, however, masks hidden complexities.

V DESIGNING THE GUIDELINES

In its response to the Ergas Committee’s proposals the government indicated[28] that it wants three things from the guidelines which the ACCC is to issue.

The ACCC does have overseas models to assist it in carrying out those three quite distinct tasks. Not all of these models point in the same direction. Nor do they use the same analytical techniques. All have their blind spots. Stripped to their essentials the choice of methodologies is as follows:

First, the guidelines could be industry specific. Much as practitioners and industry participants might welcome information and communications technology specific rules this seems to have been ruled out by the Ergas Committee who thought that Part IIIA and Part XIC were not well designed for handling intellectual property rights.

Secondly, the guidelines could be practice specific, the approach used in the European Union in relation to patents and know how.[29] This approach proceeds by listing restrictions and conditions in intellectual property licences and classifying them on a scale of yes,[30] no[31] and maybe. While useful in answering scope of grant questions, practice specific guidelines will always under or over regulate because they ignore market power.

Thirdly, the guidelines can be outcome directed, that is they look at gains and losses to both the competitive process and efficiency. This approach is adopted in the United States[32] and Canada.[33] While admirably suited to dealing with both the application of the substantial lessening of competition test and the authorisation question they have the drawback that, being drafted as aspirational objectives, they provide little detailed guidance to anyone faced with a client who demands to know right now without ifs or buts: ‘Does this clause breach the Act?’

Bearing these models in mind how should the ACCC design its intellectual property guidelines? Each phase of the task will need to be approached differently.

(a) Scope of grant guidelines The object here will be to, first, allocate a particular restriction to the appropriate ‘saved’ or ‘dammed’ pen and then to indicate the likely fate of the latter when subjected to the full rigour of the per se prohibitions and purpose based liability imposed by the rest of Part IV and how it might be redrafted to avoid this result. The skills required for this purpose will be those of the intellectual property lawyer who has a thorough understanding of what each type of intellectual property right authorises owners to do or prevent.[34] They will face two problems:
(b) Substantial lessening of competition guidelines These will need to indicate the factors used to:
(c) The authorisation analysis Here the core issue is likely to be the generation of countervailing efficiencies. In the intellectual property environment one would expect there to be a greater emphasis on innovative efficiency than its allocative or productive brethren. It would be sensible for the guidelines to require applicants to quantify efficiency gains[42] although this may be difficult with new and unproven technology. Factors which the ACCC may take into account include:

VI POTENTIALLY ASSAILABLE PRACTICES

How would licensing practices fare under the as yet virtual guidelines described above? As many commentators have observed, the process of digitisation associated with the convergence of content and communication technologies in the information and communications industries has brought about new configurations of power and behaviour.[45] The following discussion focuses on constraints and conditions in software licences and assignments that may be caught under s 51(3) if and when it is amended. The analysis necessarily takes into account two important and closely related features of information and communications technology. The first is the fact that collaboration among players in the industry is far from uncommon. (Indeed ‘teaming up’ and the formation of alliances to combine technological inputs by multiple right holders are strategies often highly conducive both to innovation itself and returns obtained on that innovation.) The second is that intellectual property rights (particularly copyright and patents) do not always neatly translate into software and other associated goods or services.[46] Software (especially that depending on the interoperability of operating system platforms, application systems, application programming interfaces and internet and digital communications technology) will often incorporate works or processes protected under a whole raft of copyrights and/or patents (frequently with multiple owners). The ensuing cross licensing thicket may be the only effective means of ensuring that pooled expertise and the intellectual property rights that go with it actually end up in the hands of those who can best exploit the software.[47] That said, application of the substantial lessening of competition test to any agreement or arrangement in the computer or any other industry mandates a search for anti-competitive effects. In that search particular attention will have to paid to arrangements which although vertical or diagonal in form are horizontal in outcome. (This is not to say that horizontal arrangements should always be unlawful, merely that they have a greater capacity to foreclose markets, particularly narrowly defined innovation markets.) They are particularly likely to be found in cases where but for the software licensing agreement or arrangement in issue the parties would have been competitors. Where such an agreement or arrangement facilitates a firm’s ability to exercise market power on its own account or in concert with another party and has (or is likely to have) an effect on the price, quantity or quality of the software or raises a rival’s costs of producing a substitutable or interoperable product or process it will be at risk under the new test.

A Abuse of Standard Setting Process by Competitors

Virtually all firms involved with the information and communications technology infrastructure will have occasion to co-operate or collaborate in standard setting or comply with standards set by others, standards that fundamentally alter the nature of competition. Where a standard becomes widely adopted the market shrinks to encompass only those products that adhere to that standard. Where there is no existing standard, competition ‘for the standard’ will be intense especially in those markets characterised by network effects[48] precisely because they are likely to tip to a single format or technology.[49] After the battle is won the standard setter will hope to enjoy less competition from competing technologies.[50] Suppose then, that parties agree among themselves to make only products or provide services that comply or are interoperable with a certain standard. When is such an agreement likely to pass the substantial lessening of competition test? For a particular standard setting exercise among competitors or potential competitors to remain under both competition and efficiency thresholds, its outcome would have to be considered to have strong pro-competitive potential and/or confer a public benefit by ensuring products are compatible with each other. The agreement would, however, be likely to be found anti-competitive if diverts and/or sinks all or most of a rival’s research and development resources. A case in point here is Dell Computer Corporation.[51] There Dell agreed with its competitors to work towards a standard for the Video Electronics Standards Association. All participating firms assured each other (on more than one occasion) that they held no intellectual property rights which would block others from developing towards the standard. Only when the standard was successful did Dell claim it infringed on its patent and seek royalties from its competitors. As Australian law now stands the agreement would be anti-competitive under s 45A if revealed as being largely a device for price control or fixing or demonstrating an anti-competitive purpose under s 45. Post Ergas, the standard would have to be shown to be both pervasive and irreversible.

B Pooling Software Patents

Software patent pooling arrangements between competitors may be struck down if they foreclose future innovation without conferring pro-competitive benefits. These may arise where blocking patents are cleared and expensive infringement litigation is avoided or when the agreement facilitates the integration of complementary technologies and the parties are able to thereby reduce their research and development costs.

One useful pointer as to how far horizontal patent pooling may lawfully go is contained in the Canadian Competition Bureau Intellectual Property Enforcement Guidelines (2000)[52] which identify as vulnerable[53] an arrangement whereby two firms agree to pool patents (the same logic also applies to software copyright pooling) but only one firm is likely to infringe the other’s intellectual property right when it puts its product on the market. In the Bureau’s view such a patent pooling practice would amount to an agreement to prevent price competition between the parties. Their guidelines suggest that two firms in a patent pooling arrangement will only escape having their practice declared anti-competitive where they both are blocked from using their own technology because it infringes on the other’s patent and neither is able to ‘invent around’ the other’s blocking patent. Should the end result be that if the patent pooling arrangements in question are not necessary for new technology to enter the market they will, on this way of looking at things, have no pro-competitive saving graces. Rather worrying, however, is the suggestion implicit in the Canadian guidelines that the competition authority might in some circumstances be prepared to jump in itself and assess the strength of the patent infringement claim before considering whether the potentially infringing party can invent around the patent. How well is a competition authority placed to carry out this kind of complex analysis? Courts and patent offices find it difficult enough to test the merits of patents and copyrights claimed over software, computer implemented business methods, computer screen displays and interfaces.[54] That a regulator would be equipped to do better seems unlikely.

C Third Line Forcing and Bundling

Third line forcing and bundling are pervasive in the computer industry. They are also plausibly represented as innovatively efficient. Such claims need to be subjected to close scrutiny. In such scrutiny issues of market definition and barriers to entry would be expected to loom large. Suppose, for example, a computer supplier A requires its customers to have the hardware it supplies maintained by B if they want to receive software maintenance and support services from A. Since these arrangements are vertical, the competition analysis will rest on market definition. If a separate market exists for the provision of maintenance services for A’s hardware, A would inevitably have power in that market. Should no distinct market be able to be identified for A’s hardware, A’s power in it would be insubstantial or non existent. If enough users consider that their total outlay on a computer system spread over its expected lifespan includes hardware maintenance costs as part of their original decision to purchase the system then a single market could be identified. It would include not only the primary product (the computer hardware) but also the secondary service (maintenance and support). The difficulty with this kind of analysis is that it assumes that barriers to entry are structural rather than behavioural and ignores the inhibitory effect on entry or exit of the bundling scheme itself. To require software licensees to purchase or licence certain products or services from licensors or third parties where this cannot be justified on the grounds of quality control or technical efficiency and then argue that consumers have set the boundaries of the market with their wallets may be putting the analytical cart before the analytical horse. Since the problem in such cases is one of characterising or measuring barriers to entry, guidelines based on market share will be of less assistance here.

Not only may restrictions on unbundling suites or compilations of computer programs and reselling or relicensing individual programs be found to be anti-competitive on the facts, they may also lie outside the scope of the relevant grant as a matter of law. Under the two step test proposed by the Ergas Committee and retained in the Government Response for the per se provisions in ss 45, 45A and 47 this would introduce some highly artificial distinctions into Australian competition enforcement. Bundling one’s own products or services must already surmount a substantial lessening of competition hurdle and would continue to have to do so under the government’s proposals. Forcing licencees to consume the products of others, however, might (on one interpretation of the government’s methodology) lose the benefit of the substantial lessening of competition test proposed for s 47(6) if it is outside the scope of grant. But not all forms of third line forcing will be outside the grant. [55] A further distinction can be made here between the sale of physical objects such as CD-ROMS through which software is loaded onto a computer and the licensing of that software. Thus, in one United States copyright infringement case such a provision in an end user licence agreement was found to be unenforceable since the intellectual property owner’s right were exhausted under the first sale provisions in the copyright statute.[56] Were an Australian court to take a similar line (nothing turns for this purpose on the exhaustion of rights rule being judicially inferred rather than expressly legislated) the competition analysis would be unnecessarily complicated by a search for the boundaries between sale and licence.

D Best Endeavours Clauses

A licensing arrangement may stipulate in relation to a copyrighted computer program or electronic database that the licensee employ its best endeavours to exploit the product and not use, sell or license competing programs or databases. Being on all fours with that considered in Transfield it is likely to be found within the scope of grant even if the clumsy ‘relates to’ were to survive a drafting cull. Post Ergas, liability would then depend on market definition and power.

E Lump Sum Fees and Output Restrictions

A licensing arrangement which stipulates in relation to a copyrighted computer program or electronic database that the licensee pay a large upfront license fee which is deductible from later royalties earned by the licensee appears to be both within the scope of grant and competitively harmless unless the licensor has market power. On the other hand a requirement that the licensee produce a minimum quantity of the product made using the software coupled with a restriction on the use of other intellectual property rights to compete with the products made using the licensed intellectual property right may foreclose the market and certainly would be beyond the grant. Once again, it is difficult to see what guidelines have to offer here. If they are outcome oriented the nature of the practice will tell market players nothing that they need to know while to ban or bless either practice outright would be to impose a wholly spurious certainty on the debate.

F Negating Infringement Defences

Usually it will be the right owner who seeks to come within the four walls of the intellectual property right so as to avoid the application of purpose tests and per se prohibitions. Sometimes, however, it will be competitors or users who complain that the condition or arrangement in question seeks to cut back rights guaranteed to them under the relevant intellectual property statute. In such a case the restriction is at risk of falling outside the scope of the grant because it impinges on a defence against infringement which would otherwise be available to the licensee. Into this category may fall copyright licences prohibiting reverse engineering, disassembly or decompilation of software. These may arguably fall outside the scope of the grant because of the new division 4A of the Copyright Act 1968 (Cth).[57] This allows a software licensee to reproduce (including by decompilation) a legitimate copy of a computer program (not a pirated one) in certain circumstances, namely:

Software licensors who attempt to pre-empt some or all or part of these fair use provisions by contract are placing themselves beyond the intellectual property statute’s protective umbrella.[58] Thus if an end user license stipulates that there is to be no reverse engineering, modification or testing the security of the program, not only will such provisions be unenforceable, they will also be, if the Government Response is enacted intact, beyond the protection of s 51(3). Since their purpose is arguably to substantially lessen competition they will be at risk under s 45 whether or not their effect is proven to be (or to be likely to be) anti-competitive on the facts. On the other hand where a computer program is patented as well as copyrighted there is no scope of grant problem on the patent side because no comparable statutory fair use defence exists for patent infringement in Australia. This threatens to introduce a wholly illogical distinction into the enforcement equation, one which it is impossible to justify on policy grounds and which demonstrates the inherent difficulties in bringing both parts of the Ergas Committee’s two step test together in a coherent statutory scheme.

G Grant Back Provisions and Continuing Obligations

Clauses which require licensees to surrender to the licensor their own intellectual property rights are often regarded as competitively suspect. Whether this is in fact so will largely depend on the degree to which the rights surrendered cover products for which there are no clear substitutes. If no such substitutes are discernible on the technological horizon the grant back will be at risk even if it is not complete. To take but one example, suppose the licensor of a computer assisted design system imposes the condition that it is to be a joint copyright owner of any works the licensed user produces using the expert system (whether it be the design of a new building, boat or nose). These run the risk of being construed as attempts to leverage the market power conferred by the copyright into other markets and as such are both beyond the grant and potentially anti-competitive. Equally problematic are attempts to project the licensor’s market power (where it exists) beyond the statutory life of the intellectual property right in question such as provisions that the licensee not exploit the intellectual property right once the term of protection for that right has expired or post expiry obligations to make royalty payments.

VII CONCLUSION

This paper was researched and written without the benefit of sighting either the Dawson Report or the actual wording of an amended s 51(3). Nevertheless it now seems unlikely that there will be any legislative retreat from the position adopted in the Government Response. If enacted in their present form the government’s proposals will only marginally tilt the competition balance against intellectual property owners and licensees. Most licensing arrangements will survive a substantial lessening of competition test if it is applied to them. The real objection to the government’s proposals is not that they disturb existing expectations (these being no more relevant here than in any regulatory context) but that they do so in ways which are both economically illiterate and unnecessarily complex. If the government were, however, to have last minute second thoughts we would suggest that they might usefully note the following observations.

First, it is probably unwise to enact a special competition regime for intellectual property rights before reforming Part IV as a whole. Secondly, when and if Part IV is overhauled, the starting assumption should be that its provisions fall equally on all types of property. From this it would follow that purpose tests and per se liability should either apply to all market players or none. It would also mean there would be no need to distinguish between different forms of per se liability. Section 51(3) would then be redundant. Should this view be rejected and the section retained in some form, the scope of grant issue would have to be tidied up by finding a more appropriate form of words than ‘relates to’ as the connecting link between right and exemption. The question of non statutory rights also needs to be re-examined. It cannot simply be sidelined. Finally, drafting infelicities and conceptual lacunae cannot be cured by enforcement guidelines, especially if those guidelines are pulled in different directions by unclear and incompatible objectives.


[*] Professor of Law, University of Auckland.

[**] Senior Lecturer in Commercial Law, University of Auckland.

[1] Refusals to license and misuse of market power under s 46 of the Trade Practices Act 1974 (Cth) (TPA) are not addressed in what follows. They are exhaustively and illuminatingly analysed in S Corones, ‘Technological Tying in the Computer Industry: When Does it Contravene Section 46 of the Trade Practice Act?’ (2003) 3 Queensland University of Technology Law and Justice Journal 48.

[2] A Blayse, Subsection 51(3) of the Trade Practices Act 1974 and the Interaction of Intellectual Property and Competition Law 3 <http://www.necg.com.au/pappub/papers-blayse-iptalk-may01.pdf> .

[3] For an analysis of the social and economic drivers of this process of intellectual property expansionism see I Eagles, ‘Intellectual Property and Competition Policy: The Case for Neutrality’ in CER Rickett and G W Austin (eds) International Intellectual Property Law and the Common Law World (2000) 285.

[4] L Longdin, ‘Parallel Importing Post TRIPS: Convergence and Divergence in Australia and New Zealand’ (2001) 50 International and Comparative Law Quarterly 54.

[5] For a typical reaction see the submissions of the Australian Information Industry Association to the Review of the Trade Practices Act, July 2002 (‘AIIA Submissions’).

[6] Review of Intellectual Property Legislation under the Competition Principles Agreement, Final Report, Commonwealth of Australia, (September 2000).

[7] See <http://www.law.gov.au/WWW/SECURITYLAWHOME.NSF/Web+Pages/A6C3825011D8A8B1CA256C330000CF9A?OpenDocument> at 11 February 2003.

[8] Section 51(3) provides that:

A contravention of a provision of this Part other than section 46, 46A or 48 shall not be taken to have been committed by reason of:

(a) the imposing of, or giving effect to, a condition of:

(i) a licence granted by the proprietor, licensee or owner of a patent, of a registered design, or of a copyright, or of such EL rights within the meaning of the Circuit Layouts Act 1989, or by a person who has applied for a patent or for the registration of a design; or

(ii) an assignment of a patent, of a registered design, of a copyright or of such EL rights, or of the right to apply for a patent or for the registration of a design;

to the extent that the condition relates to:

(iii) the invention to which the patent or application for a patent relates or articles made by the use of that invention;

(iv) goods in respect of which the design is, or is proposed to be, registered and to which it is applied;

(v) the work or other subject matter in which the copyright subsists; or

(vi) the eligible layout in which the EL rights subsist;

(b) the inclusion in a contract, arrangement or understanding authorizing the use of a certification trade mark of a provision in accordance with the rules applicable under Part XI of the Trade Marks Act 1955, or the giving effect to such provision; or

(c) the inclusion in a contract, arrangement or understanding between:

(i) the registered proprietor of a trade mark other than a certification trade mark; and

(ii) a person registered as a registered user of that trade mark under Part IX of the Trade Marks Act 1955 or a person authorized by the contract to use the trade mark subject to his or her becoming registered as such a registered user;

of a provision to the extent that it relates to the kinds, qualities or standards of goods bearing the mark that may be produced or supplied, or the giving effect to the provision to that extent.

[9] It is assumed for present purposes that licences and assignments involving software fall under the definition of either ‘goods’ or ‘services’ under the TPA even when software is not supplied via any physical medium such as a disk, CD-ROM or DVD but is installed directly on machines or supplied on line via the Internet. Given the different modes of supply and the inherent nature of the software supplied (a digital stream of zeros and ones) it is not surprising that judicial interpretation of consumer protection statutes in Australia and the United Kingdom has failed to produce a clear bright line answer as to whether or when software is ‘goods’ or ‘services’ a hybrid of them both or whether it is neither and just falls through the statutory cracks. See Toby Construction Products Pty Ltd v Computer Sales Pty Ltd [1983] 2 NSWLT 48; Beta Computers (Europe) Ltd v Adobe Systems (Europe) Ltd [1996] EWCA Civ 1296; [1996] 4 All ER 481 and St Albans City Council v International Computers Ltd [1996] EWCA Civ 1296; [1997] FSR 251. Under s 4 TPA, while the definition of ‘goods’ is not exhaustive it seems that software would have to be equated with ‘electricity’ to be caught. If software is a ‘service’ as seems more likely, it would have to be squeezed under a ‘[right (including a right in relation to or interest in real or personal property), benefit, privilege or facility that is to be granted or conferred in trade or commerce].’ To clarify the position in New Zealand ‘software’ is deemed to be goods under the Commerce Act 1986 by the Consumer Protection (Definition of Goods and Services) Bill 2002.

[10] At least under ss 47(2) and (3) as opposed to s 47(6) of the TPA according to ACCC v Universal Music Pty Ltd [2000] FCA 1800. See also Broederbund Software Inc v Computermate Products Aust Pty Ltd (1992) ATPR 41-155.

[11] Unlike its New Zealand equivalent which has no application to business acquisitions, see Commerce Act 1986 (NZ), s 45.

[12] Eagles, above n 3, 329; S Corones, Competition Law in Australia (2nd ed, Sydney, 1999) 301.

[13] For an example of the rebuttable presumption approach to scope of grant see Image Technical Services v Eastman Kodak [1997] USCA9 2479; 125 F 3d 1195 (9th Cir, 1997). While there are other decisions of the Federal Circuit which suggest a substantial role for ‘scope of grant’ (see In Re Independent Services Organisation Antitrust Litigation [2000] USCAFED 54; 203 F 3d 1322 (Fed Cir, 2000) these cannot stand with the more considered rejection of ‘scope of grant’ as an absolute defence as in United States v Microsoft [2001] USCADC 115; 253 F 3d 34, 63 (DC Cir, 2001). See below text accompanying n 23. In the European Union ‘scope of grant’ has been an evidentiary presumption not a substantive exemption although the strength of that presumption varies (cf Radio Telefis Eirean and Independent Television Publications v EC Commission and Magill (1995) 4 MLR 718 with Oscar Bronner v Mediaprint [1999] 4 CMLR 112. See also Phillips Electronics v Ingman Ltd [1999] FSR 112).

[14] (1980) ATPR 40-166.

[15] There is a third viewpoint which would construe the words of s 51(3) purely purposively so that they related only to the subject matter of the grant. As pointed out to the Ergas Committee by the Australian Government Solicitor’s ‘Memorandum of Advice’ (January 2000) this would make the exemption ineffectual since most such stipulations would not breach the TPA. (It might be added that this third way is rather copyright centric and not easily applied to forms of intellectual property where rights are not affirmatively stated in the relevant statute.)

[16] This is unproven. The boundaries of copyright are not obviously more tightly drawn than those of breach of confidence, for example, especially in relation to the limitations imposed by freedom of expression. In both cases the boundaries are largely judge drawn. A more cogent objection is the fact that (head starts apart) breach of confidence only protects information while it remains secret. Contractual limitations on the use of trade secrets on the other hand are not similarly constrained.

[17] Plant Breeders’ Rights Act 1994 (Cth).

[18] National Competition Council, Review of Sections 51(2) and 51(3) of the Trade Practices Act 1974 Final Report, Commonwealth of Australia, March 1999. This was something of a retreat from its interim view that s 51(3) should vanish from the statute book entirely; see also Draft Report, November 1988, 6, 96.

[19] Review of Intellectual Property Legislation under the Competition Principles Agreement Final Report, Commonwealth of Australia, (September 2000) 21.

<http://www.ipcr.gov.au/finalreport1dec/trade_marks_act4.htm> . The terms of reference for the Ergas Committee required it to have regard to the conclusions and recommendations in the National Competition Council’s Final Report, above n 18.

[20] As to the competing legal and economic theories which fuel this debate, see M A Carrier, ‘Unraveling the Patent -Antitrust Paradox’ (2002) 150 University of Pennsylvania Law Review 761 and Eagles, above n 3, 292.

[21] New Zealand provides a possible model here (if one is needed). There the statutory exemption for intellectual property dealings protects clauses in intellectual property licences which authorise ‘any act which would otherwise be prohibited’ by the right in question in s 45(1)(a) of the Commerce Act 1986. The New Zealand provision, however, suffers from the drawback that it does not include positive ‘best endeavours’ stipulations of the kind resorted to in Transfield. For more appropriate phrasing, see Eagles, above n 3, 328.

[22] [2001] USCADC 115; 253 F 3d 34 (DC Cir, 2001).

[23] Ibid 63. The DC Circuit’s treatment of the copyright issue, although brief, signals to right holders in the United States that the boundaries of intellectual property rights will not be allowed to determine the extent of antitrust scrutiny. Instead of asking ‘what does copyright allow its owner to do?’ and granting antitrust immunity to conduct within the four walls of that legislative authority, the Court instead engaged in a much more forensic analysis which identified those aspects of the intellectual property right most in need of protection through restrictive licensing and balanced the pro- and anticompetitive effects of such licensing in the normal case by case way. For discussion of Microsoft’s copyright arguments see I Eagles and L Longdin, ‘The Microsoft Appeal: Different Rules for Different Markets?’ (2001) 7 New Zealand Business Law Quarterly 296, 312-313.

[24] See above n 19, 20.

[25] In this they were surely right. The statutory divide between rule of reason and per se in Australia would have few defenders amongst economists these days. A statutory regime which bans third line forcing outright now looks like a survivor from an earlier age of American jurisprudence. Unfortunately the Australian statute leaves judges no room for the prudent retreat which their US brethren have been able to beat. See US v Jerrold Economics Corp 187 F Supp 545 (1960); Northwest Wholesale Stationers v Pacific Stationary and Printing Co [1985] USSC 154; 472 US 284 (1985). The rigidity of the per se rule forces Australian courts to either deny economic reality (see Radio 2UE Sydney Pty Ltd v Stereo FM Pty Ltd [1982] FCA 206; (1982) 62 FLR 437) or adopt unnatural interpretations of the statutory words, see Castlemaine Tooheys Ltd v Williams and Hodgson Transport Pty Ltd (1997) ATPR 70-003.

[26] Section 47 is a case in point here. It starts by way of banning exclusive dealing in fairly general terms and then proceeds to list various subcategories of such dealing some of which are explicitly made subject to tests of anti-competitive purpose or effect while others are left to languish in per se limbo. To an outsider’s eye all this seems rather odd. Why treat exclusive dealing separately when there is s 45(1)(b) to fall back on?

[27] It is now within the terms of reference of the committee chaired by Sir Daryl Dawson which was set up in May 2002 to review the competition and authorisation provisions of the TPA.

[28] See above n 7.

[29] Technology Transfer Block Exemption 1996. The block exemption proceeds by way of a white list of permitted practices, a black list of definitely non exempt (but not necessarily unlawful) practices and a grey list of practices whose presence in an agreement does not defeat its exemption on other grounds. The White List (Art 1) includes exclusive licences and territorial restrictions associated with technology transfer that are limited to the life of the intellectual property (or ten years in the case of pure know-how agreements). The Grey List (Art 2) includes obligations to keep know-how secret, not to grant sublicenses, to terminate agreements where licensees challenge the validity of the licensor’s intellectual property rights, and to use best endeavours to manufacture and market the licensed product. The Black List (Art 3) includes restrictions on the selling prices of licensed products (resale price maintenance), restrictions on the quantities to be made or sold, bans on competing technologies, customer restrictions between competing manufacturers, obligations to grant-back improvements, and territorial restrictions for a duration longer than as provided under the White List. The effect of all this is not as clear cut as it seems. The benefit of the exemption may be withdrawn if the activity in question is shown to be anti-competitive in fact (Art 7). The European approach is further complicated by the need to show that the licence does not impede the flow of goods between member states. It also needs to be remembered that the technology transfer exemption does not apply to copyright or trademarks unless they are ancillary to patented technology and know how. The United Kingdom regulator follows a similar methodology, see J Maitland-Walker, ‘Competition Act 1998: OFT’s Technical Guidelines on Application of Competition Rules to Intellectual Property Rights’ [2002] European Competition Law Review 311.

[30] The European Union white list offers some useful pointers here. The list is set out in R Whish, Competition Law (4th ed, 2001) 693.

[31] Ibid 694. The European Union black list is less useful being obviously more affected by free movement concerns.

[32] United States Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission’s Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (1995).

[33] Canadian Competition Bureau Intellectual Property Enforcement Guidelines (2000) <http://competition.ic.ca> .

[34] This is a simple black letter test. There is no room in such cases for the holistic quasi moral rights arguments resorted to by the defendant in the Microsoft litigation and rejected by the court in that case. Judge Penfold Jackson’s difficulties with Microsoft’s scope of grant copyright arguments at first instance lay in the company’s inability or failure to pinpoint which of its exclusive rights as copyright owner (as laid down in the copyright statute) were supposedly being protected by the restrictive licensing provisions. Had Microsoft pleaded the right to make an adaptation (or derivative work, in United States copyright parlance) instead of relying on the existence of a penumbra of implied rights lurking somewhere behind the specific grant of power in the copyright law, it may have succeeded on this point at the trial (although not on appeal). See Eagles and Longdin, above n 23, 313.

[35] Eagles, above n 3, 329.

[36] Courts and regulators need to do more than reach for their crystal ball. The guidelines should only take account of developments which are both identifiable and reasonably imminent.

[37] Eagles, above n 3, 304; H Ergas, ‘Intellectual Property Rights and Competition.’ (Paper presented to the Federal Trade Commission/Department of Justice Hearings on Antitrust and Intellectual Property and Law in the Knowledge-Based Economy. Washington DC, 23 May 2002, para 122w).

[38] Market share is a negative not a positive test of market power in this context.

[39] Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property, issued by the US Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, 6 April 1995. The guidelines are set out in [1995] 7 EIPR Supp 3.

[40] Canadian Competition Bureau Intellectual Property Enforcement Guidelines (2000) para 5.2.1.

[41] In high technology markets arguments that today’s market power will be overcome by tomorrow’s discoveries is double edged. In fast moving markets delays in innovation may matter more, see Eagles and Longdin, above n 23, 304.

[42] As routinely required in merger cases, see the ACCC’s Merger Guidelines. Corones, above n 12, 55.

[43] Wattyl (Australia) Pty Ltd v Courtauld’s (Australia) Pty Ltd & Ors (1996) ATPR (Com) 50-232.

[44] Telstra Corporation v Australian Performing Rights Association Ltd (1998) ATPR (Com) 50-256.

[45] See, eg, A Murray and C Scott, ‘Controlling the New Media: Hybrid Responses to New Forms of Power’ (2002) 65 Modern Law Review 491, 493.

[46] H Ergas, ‘Intellectual Property Rights and Competition.’ (Paper presented to the Federal Trade Commission/Department of Justice Hearings on Antitrust and Intellectual Property and Law in the Knowledge-Based Economy, Washington DC, 23 May 2002) 22.

[47] Ibid.

[48] It is freely acknowledged nowadays that information and communication technologies based on connectedness are largely driven by such ‘network effects’. Underlying this analysis is the notion that networks become increasingly more compelling and valuable as more and more people use them. See M L Katz and C Shapiro, ‘Network Externalities, Competition and Compatibility’ (1985) 75 American Economics Review 424; and ‘Systems Competition and Network Effects’ (1994) 8 Journal of Economic Perspectives 93, 95. The theory emphasises that additional users confer positive externalities on existing users, leading to positive feedback effects for technology that is adopted and conversely negative feedback effects for that which is not adopted. Where markets for goods or services derive a relatively high portion of their value from being part of a network (rather than the value they would have were they to stand alone), these effects may play a significant role in establishing the structure of the market and the strategies pursued by firms in the market: see M A Lemley and D McGowan, ‘Legal Implications of Network Effects’ (1998) 86 California Law Review 479, 488.

[49] As the economic theory runs: in markets characterised by network effects, one product or standard ‘tips’ towards dominance because as mentioned above ‘the utility that a user derives from its consumption increases with the number of other agents consuming it’: see M Katz and C Shapiro, ‘Network Externalities, Competition and Compatibility’ (1985) 75 American Economics Review 424; and ‘Systems Competition and Network Effects’ (1994) 8 Journal of Economic Perspectives 93, 95. With software innovation, this can happen very quickly. Economists describe it as ‘instant scalability’. Losers do not remain in these markets, especially where the product is supported by (or consists of) intellectual property rights: see S J Liebowitz and S E Margolis, Winners, Losers and Microsoft: Competition and Antitrust in High Technology, Independent Institute (1999) 137.

[50] C Shapiro, ‘Competition Policy and Innovation’ (Working Paper Series of the OECD Directorate for Science, Technology and Industry, DSTI/DOC, 2002) 11, 25 <http://www.oecd.org/sti/working-papers> .

[51] C-3658 (May 20, 1996) Consent Order. As cited by W J Baer, ‘Antitrust Enforcement and High Technology Markets’ (1998) <http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/other/ipat6.htm> . The case depended on findings of anti-competitive intent as well as outcome. The former would play no part in the Ergas scheme.

[52] Canadian Competition Bureau Intellectual Property Enforcement Guidelines (2000) 22-23 <http://competition.ic.ca> .

[53] Under s 45, the conspiracy provision, in the Competition Act, RS, 1985, C-34.

[54] R P Merges, ‘As Many As Six Impossible Patents Before Breakfast: Property Rights For Business Concepts and Patent System Reform’ (2002) 14 Berkeley Technology Law Journal 577.

[55] Just how complicated this might become can be seen when one looks at the current investigation by the European Commission into Microsoft Corporation’s integration of Windows Media Player into its Windows operating system. Under the Government Response such bundling would be tested for pro and anti-competitive effects but not so necessarily should Microsoft back Pressplay (streaming media software produced by a music joint venture between Sony and Universal) against MusicNet (streaming media software produced by AOL/Time Warner and Realnetworks).

[56] See Softman v Adobe 171 F Supp 2d 1975 (C D Cal, 2001). Adobe had bundled four of its products including the well known Acrobat, PageMaker, and Photoshop into a software suite ‘Adobe Collections’ and sold the collection on CD-ROMs for less (US$1000) than the four programs if sold separately (US$1700). Adobe inserted a term into the end user licence agreement (EULA) that the end user may ‘transfer all [his] rights to the use of the software to another person or entity provided that [he] also transfer the EULA and all the software, hardware bundled or preinstalled with the software.’

[57] Introduced by the Copyright Amendment (Computer Programs) Act 1999 especially to deal with the copying of computer programs.

[58] It is safe, however, for software copyright licensees to stipulate in end user licence agreements that there is to be no sublicensing, reassignment, lending, renting, leasing, creation of adaptations of protected programs since these restrictions merely reaffirm the exclusive rights set out in s 31 of the Copyright Act 1968 (Cth).


AustLII: Feedback | Privacy Policy | Disclaimers
URL: http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/QUTLJJ/2003/3.html


AustLII: Copyright Policy | Disclaimers | Privacy Policy | Feedback
URL: http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/QUTLawJJl/2003/3.html